1. Introduction
The optimal investment of Merton model introduced in [
12,
13] has been investigated by researchers and extended in different contexts since it appears. One important extension in continuous time is due to Magill and Constantinides [
11], where a linear transaction costs function is used in the context of Merton problem. In discrete time, the study of Merton model with linear transaction costs was developed by Jouini and Kallal in [
8]. We can also cite the papers of Shreve and Soner [
14] which extended Merton problem by including viscosity theory and Cetin, Jarrow and Protter [
3] which studied the Merton model for illiquid markets.
Recently, Chebbi and Soner in [
1] extend the Merton model in discrete time and finite horizon to the case of market with frictions represented by a convex penalty function defined for one investor. They proved the existence of an optimal strategy by solving a dynamic optimization problem. Then Ounaies, Bonnisseau, Chebbi and Soner in [
15] extend this model to the infinite horizon and and they proved the existence of optimal strategy by an argument of fixed points.
In this paper, we will take this direction of extension in order to prove the existence of optimal strategy in Merton model for market frictions in infinte horizon when there are finite number of investors. our approach is very different and based on constructing an equivalent general equilibrium model with multiple agents. The idea to use the general equilibrium theory is inspired by the paper of Le Van and Dana [
10].
Sections of this paper are organized as follow: In
Section 2, We give a description of Merton model of investment problem in infinite horizon and with market frictions modeled by convex) penalty functions defined for each investor and constraints conditions about liquidation value is defined consequently.
In
Section 3, we construct an equivalent general equilibrium economy model to Merton model of investment.
In
Section 4, we prove the the existence of an equilibrium for the model of general equilibrium economy and the optimal strategy of Merton problem of invested will be this obtained equilibrium.
2. The Model
Let be the probability space where is the space of events . For , let be the -field generated by the canonical mapping process . We denote by , where is the trivial -algebra and by , the probability measure.
In the discrete time model of this paper, we suppose that the market is with a money market account paying a return
and
N risky assets that provide a random return of
with values in
that are supposed to be identically and independently distributed over time. We denote by
, the strictly positive asset price process that will is supposed to satisfy the following condition:
where
is the initial stock value. The return vector at time
t is given by
,
,
Then
’s are
-measurable and consequently,
is an
-valued,
-adapted process. The process p is an
-valued
-adapted process.
In our multi-investors model, we suppose that there is a finite number
m of investors labeled
i,
. Each investor has to choose a portfolio of assets
j,
. We denote by
, the individual
i’s process of money invested in the
j-th stock at any time
t prior to the portfolio adjustment. The riskless asset
will be the process of money invested in the money market account at any time
t. Shares are traded at determined price vector
. For
, the process
will denote the number of shares held by the
i-th investor at time
t with values in
and we have:
In our model of markets with frictions, we assume that there is a penalty function
for each investor
i due to transaction costs. The dynamics of the riskless asset will be as follow:
where the
-adapted process
denotes the
consumption of the
i-th investor, and
is the portfolio adjustment process given by:
Note taht rebalancing of portfolio will occur between time
t and time
and it is easy to see that:
and the mark-to-market value is given by:
4. Existence of Equilibrium
We will use the following standard assumptions in order to prove the existence of equilibrium:
- Assumption (H1): For each , is continuously differentiable, strictly increasing and concave function satisfying , .
- Assumption (H2): At initial period 0, , and for with .
- Assumption (H3): is convex with and for .
- Assumption (H4): The utility of each agent
i is finite:
We now constructed the
T-truncated economy
as
in which we suppose that there are no activities from period
to the infinity and by using a classical argument, we compactify this economy by using the bounded economy
as
in which all random variables are bounded. Consider a finite-horizon bounded economy which goes on for
periods:
with
defined by:
The solvency set is given by:
Now, we define the economy
, for each
such that
, by adding
units for each agent at date 0. This condition assure the non-emptiness of the solvency set. Thus, the feasible set of each agent
i will be:
Lemma 4.1. The set is non empty, for .
Proof. Indeed,
Now, since
, we can select
and
such that
□
Lemma 4.2. The set has convex values.
Proof. Now we want to show that
is convex. Take
, for
and
. For
, we note by
and similarly
,
. We have:
since
g is convex and
for
and
.
□
For simplicity, we denote .
Lemma 4.3. is lower semi-continuous correspondence on and is upper semi-continuous with compact convex values.
Proof. Since is non-empty and has open graph, then it is lower semi-continuous correspondence. Since is compact and the correspondence has a closed graph, then is upper semi-continuous with compact values.
□
Definition 2. The stochastic process is an equilibrium of the economy if it satisfies the following conditions:
For
, consider an element
defined on
by
where
.
Now let
be the correspondence defined by:
and for each
, consider:
Lemma 4.4. The correspondence is upper semi-continuous with non-empty, convex, compact valued for each .
Proof. This is a direct consequence of the Maximum Theorem. □
According to the Kakutani Theorem, there exists
such that
For simplicity, we denote by
Lemma 4.5. Under Assumptions (H1), (H2) and (H3), there exists an equilibrium for the finite-horizon bounded ϵ-economy .
Proof. We start proving that
and
for
Indeed, From (4.1), one can easily check that for every
, we have:
We recall the solvency constraint,
Moreover, the value of an agent’s consumption cannot exceed the value of his wealth and the following inequality will be satisfied:
By summing the inequality (4.4) over
i, we obtain that, for each
t:
If
, we deduce that
. Therefore for all
t,
, which contradicts (4.5). Hence, we obtain as a result,
.
Since prices are strictly positive and the utility functions are strictly increasing, all budget constraints are binding. By summing over
i) at date
t, we obtain:
Hence, the optimality of is from (4.2). □
Lemma 4.6. Suppose Assumptions (H1), (H2) and (H3) are satisfied, then there exists an equilibrium for the finite-horizon bounded economy .
Proof. We have proved that for each
, where
n is an integer and large enough, there exists an equilibrium denoted:
for the economy,
. Since prices and allocations are bounded, there exists a sub-sequence
such that
converges. without loss of generality, we can assume that
when
n tends to infinity. Moreover, by taking limit of market clearing conditions of the
, we obtain the corresponding conditions of the bounded truncated economy
. □
Remark 1. It should be noticed that at equilibrium, we have according to (2.1).
Lemma 4.7. For each i, is optimal.
Proof. Since , for all , there exists an agent i such that . According to Remark 1, we have . We now prove the optimality of .
Let be a feasible allocation of the maximization problem of agent i with the feasible set . We should prove that .
Since
, there exists
and
such that
converges to
. Then, for each
i, we have
Fix
h. Let
be high enough such that for every
,
. Then
Tend
n tend to infinity, we obtain
Let tends
h to infinity, we obtain
.
We have just showed that is an optimal solution. We now prove that for every t. Indeed, if , the optimality of implies that contradiction.
□
After proving the existence of the equilibrium when tends to 0, we deduce that this equilibrium holds for the truncated unbounded economy.
Lemma 4.8. An equilibrium for is an equilibrium for .
Proof. Let
be an equilibrium of
. Note that
for every
. We can see that conditions
and
in Definition (2) are satisfied. We will show that condition
is also verified. Let
be a feasible plan of agent
i. Suppose that
. For each
, we define
. By definition of
,we can choose
sufficiently close to 0 such that
. It is clear that
is a feasible allocation. By the concavity of the utility function, we have
We deduce that:
which contradicts the optimality of
.
We denote by
an equilibrium of the
T-truncated economy
. Since
, for every
,
and
.Thus, we can assume that:
when T goes to infinity.
One can easily check that all markets clear.
Now we can give the main result of this paper:
Theorem 4.1. If hypothesis (H1), (H2),(H3) and (H4) are satisfied, then there exists an equilibrium of the infinite horizon economy .
Proof. We have proved previously that for each , there exists an equilibrium for the economy . Let be a feasible allocation of the problem . We will prove that .
We define
as follows:
We can see that
.
Since
, there exists a sequence
with
and this sequence converges to
when
n tends to infinity . We have
We can choose
high enough such that
and for every
, we have
Consequently
. Therefore, we get
. Tends
s to infinity, we obtain
. Now, if we tend
n tend to infinity, we obtain
for every
T. Consequently:
Let
T tend to infinity, we obtain
Then,
Hence, we have proved the optimality of
. Note that prices
are strictly positive since the utility function of agent
i is strictly increasing.
□
The obtained equilibrium is the expected optimal strategy of Merton investment problem in the case of multi-investors and in markets with frictions formulated by a penalty functions for every investor due to loss in trading. Our model and main result extends models and results obtained by Chebbi and Soner in [
1] and by Ounaies, Bonnisseau, Chebbi and Soner in [
15]