1. Introduction
The digital economy is fundamentally altering how businesses innovate and maintain competitiveness and is continually promoting corporate growth [
1,
2]. The creation and usage of digital technologies, which are widely used by platforms, tech entrepreneurs, and users, have changed from being a disruptive wave that only affected some industries to being a key factor in global economic growth [
3,
4]. Enterprises are undergoing a digital transformation because of the information technology wave, which is transforming corporate strategies, business models, innovation policies, and marketing tactics [
5]. Digital innovations, such as the Industrial Internet of Things (IIoT), grant companies the ability to make products and services smarter [
6]; they also blur the lines between physical products and digital services [
7]; and they open up enormous opportunities for innovation [
8].
However, even in today’s rapid development of the digital economy, very few companies can survive in such a fierce market by themselves. Conceptualizing the company as an autonomous, independent entity fighting for competitive advantage does not fully explain today’s reality [
9]. In the technology-driven digital world, many of the largest and most successful companies now operate as “digital platforms.” Such organizations have subverted many industries, including retail, hotels, and taxis, and are actively entering new areas such as financial services [
10,
11]. In the past few decades, digital platforms have redefined business models, disrupted existing industries, launched new products and services, and created huge value for society [
12,
13].
However, to realize the full potential of digital platforms, a new trend in strategic development is the construction of a digital platform-based ecosystem [
14]. Ecosystem theory regards enterprises as part of a highly interdependent and interconnected network of collaborative and competitive entities. Moore [
15] believes that members of the ecosystem have common goals and visions and develop together in a dynamic business environment. In addition to the platform, the digital platform ecosystem also includes the government, enterprises, scientific research institutions, financial institutions, intermediaries, and other stakeholders. In the digital platform ecosystem, digital platforms utilize digital technologies to develop and control digital resources beyond the scope of the company, create value by facilitating multi-party connectivity, and affect enterprises through network effects [
16]. Different organizations continue to exchange knowledge and information to promote the sustainable development of digital platforms.
As digital platforms dominate, platform owners have accumulated tremendous power and influence; they often play an important role in leading key stakeholders to create value for their platform ecosystem [
17,
18,
19,
20]. However, without effective checks and balances, platform owners can sometimes lead the platform to act at other stakeholders’ expense [
13,
21,
22,
23,
24]. With time, stakeholders are paying increasing attention to the power of platform owners and the problems caused by the power imbalance between platform owners and other stakeholders [
25]. By using "platform choice," "big data to kill familiarity," "search power reduction" and other means, platforms caused by the restriction of competition, price discrimination, damage to the rights and interests of settled enterprises, and other issues have been criticized [
26]. Karle and Peitz [
27] studied the extent to which targeted advertising can be implemented in monopoly search engines. Hagiu [
28] and White [
29] consider a platform that can garble the consumer search process to redirect settled enterprises to sellers who generate higher income for the platform. Casner [
30] analyzed the motivation of platforms to increase consumer search costs in the search environment and found that platforms that charge proportionally have the incentive to confuse searches to maintain sellers’ price increases.
Therefore, in the context of the digital economy, proper governance concepts are the key to coordinating a successful platform ecosystem with all stakeholders [
31]. As Tiwana, Konsynski, and Venkatraman [
32] stated, new organizational forms enabled by IT such as digital platform ecosystems raise the questions "Who is governed?", “What is being governed?”, "What is governed?”, and "How is it governed?” Answering these questions in the right way is crucial for platform owners, particularly given the fierce competition between ecosystems [
33]. Policymakers are increasingly devoting efforts to upgrading digital infrastructures and regulating the interactions between platforms and other system participants regarding the development of the digital platform economy [
34]. However, when it comes to the governance of digital platforms, government regulation alone is insufficient. Thus, in addition to traditional government regulation, platform ecosystem governance includes two strategies. The most common strategy requires platform operators to control governance, establish policy teams, and develop research capabilities to evaluate these policies [
35,
36]. For self-management, the second strategy relies on the supervision and management of platform users and enterprises [
37,
38]. The organization and management mechanism of the digital platform can be further improved through the supervision of the enterprises, such as evaluation, feedback, complaints, and suggestions.
However, the digital platform ecosystem’s evolutionary ecosystem is not static [
39,
40]. As a complex socio-technical ecosystem, the digital platform-based ecosystem also has an unexpected evolutionary trajectory, which is still an elusive topic in the early literature [
41]. Life cycle theory proposes several stages in the evolutionary process, tracking phenomena from birth and growth to maturity and decline [
42]. Researchers and managers are paying increasing attention to understanding how platform ecosystems are formed and managed, and how they evolve over time [
43]. Teece [
44] uses a four-stage model of birth, expansion, leadership, and self-renewal to analyze the needs of each stage of the platform life cycle and its dependence on high-level dynamic capability categories. Muzellec et al. [
45] divided the development of multi-sided platforms into embryonic, emerging, growth, and maturity stages. Isckia et al. [
46] designed a life cycle for platform-based ecosystems including the birth, expansion, maturity, leadership, and renewal stages. Therefore, different digital platform development stages should have different governance methods.
The current platform literature lacks a process perspective on how the digital platform governance mechanism evolves and develops [
47]. The evolution of platform ecology is a process of gradual maturity and renewal [
48]. As some platform ecosystems have been maintained for more than ten years, researchers have begun to outline the evolution path of platform ecosystems mainly by studying life cycle models [
42]. Although these studies detail the evolution of successful platform ecosystems, they are still mostly descriptive [
49]. Researchers have realized that the digital economy architecture can evolve, the number of platform ecosystem participants will also increase over time, and there will be co-evolutionary activities [
50]. Still lacking is a systematic method to study the evolution of the digital platform governance ecosystem, particularly from the perspective of life cycle and growth [
51].
In summary, this study adopts a four-stage model of birth, expansion, leadership, and self-renewal to analyze the governance needs for each stage of the digital platform; through the evolutionary game method, we study the development of different subjects (government, platform, and settled enterprises) in the digital platform ecosystem, including co-governance effects at different stages. In the remainder of this article, we first propose model assumptions and then construct a tripartite evolutionary game model, which presents the results by constructing contributions from different platform ecosystem perspectives and influence factors. Finally, we discuss the propositions generated from this analysis to propose suggestions for digital platform ecosystem development.
5. Numerical Analysis of the Tripartite Game in Different Life Cycle Stages
Based on extant research, this study argues that the digital platform life cycle can be divided into four stages: birth, expansion, leadership, and self-renewal. Government subsidies are gradually increasing in these four development processes. With the gradual standardization of platform development, the cost of platform autonomy will be reduced, and settled enterprises’ awareness of the rights protection of platform governance will also be continuously enhanced. Consequently, the opportunity cost of settled enterprises’ participation in platform governance and the effect of platform autonomy on platform reputation will also continuously increase. Based on the above phenomena, this study conducts a numerical simulation analysis of the evolution of the digital platform’s three parties in different stages.
5.1 Birth stage
In the early stage of platform ecosystem formation, the government, platform organizations, and settled enterprises are all in the stage of continuous exploration. The government invests relatively little in platform governance, and the level of subsidies is relatively low. Platform autonomy has just started, and governance has not yet formed a scale effect, which leads to a high governance cost and the platform reputation’s small influence. As settled enterprises are new to the platform ecosystem, they do not have a clear understanding of the boundaries of their rights and interests; lack a high awareness of rights protection; and there is a high threshold to participate in platform governance. At this stage, government regulation can rapidly even out and implement positive regulation strategies, while platform organizations cannot achieve good autonomy, and settled enterprises’ participation remains weak. This corresponds to the equilibrium point (1,0,0), but this point is not the ESS of the system.
To further verify the validity of the evolutionary stability analysis, the results of a 100-time evolution through simulation of the birth stage in the digital platform ecosystem are shown in Figure 5. The three-dimensional evolution results show that in the birth stage, the stable point of the model’s layout is (1,0,0); that is, at this stage, only the government tends to valid government regulation, while the platform tends to monopolize and settled enterprises tend not to participate, which is consistent with the conclusion in
Figure 4.
5.2 Expansion stage
Figure 5.
Dynamic evolution process in the expansion stage.
Figure 5.
Dynamic evolution process in the expansion stage.
In the expansion stage of platform ecosystems, platform organizations are in the stage of explosive growth, and the government gradually attaches importance to investment in platform regulation. Platform autonomy has not adapted to the rapid enhancement of platform organizations, resulting in high governance costs. More settled enterprises have come into contact with platform organizations; however, they remain in the trial and exploration stage with enthusiasm for platform governance still not high. At this stage, governance is still dominated by government regulation, and the government can rapidly turn to the governance strategy. Although the participation of settled enterprises is still not strong, the platform autonomy strategy starts gradually and shows an upward trend. This corresponds to the ESS point (1,1,0).
On this basis, the results of a 100-time evolution through simulation of the expansion stage in the digital platform ecosystem are shown in
Figure 6. The three-dimensional evolution results show that in the expansion period, the model’s layout stability point is (1,1,0); that is, at this stage, the government still tends to valid government regulation, while the platform tends to self-governance, and settled enterprises still tend not to participate, which is consistent with the conclusion in Figure 5.
5.3 Leadership stage
In the platform ecosystem’s leadership stage, the platform organization grows further, but the development rate is relatively slow. At this time, the government continues to increase investment in platform regulation, which has gradually adapted to the platform ecosystem’s development mode, and the cost of autonomy has decreased. Settled enterprises have an improved understanding of the platform organization, a preliminary awareness of rights protection has been formed, and they are gradually willing to participate in the platform governance. At this stage, the government, platform, and settled enterprises gradually tend to balance and jointly manage the platform ecosystem. This corresponds to the equilibrium point (1,1,1).
On this basis, the results of a 100-time evolution through simulation of the leadership stage in the digital platform ecosystem are shown in
Figure 8. The three-dimensional evolution results show that in the leadership stage, the stable point of the model layout is (1,1,1); that is, in this stage, the government still tends to valid government regulation, while the platform tends to self-governance, and settled enterprises tend to participate, which is consistent with the conclusion in
Figure 7.
5.4 Self-Renewal stage
In the self-renewal stage of the platform ecosystem, platform development is relatively mature, and the government continues to invest in regulating the platform. Platform autonomy gradually normalized, leading to a decline in autonomy costs. Settled enterprises’ awareness of rights protection has greatly improved, and they can actively participate in platform governance. At this stage, both platforms and settled enterprises can rapidly reach a balance and participate in platform governance, while government decision-making gradually tends to be “ungovernance,” which means that government regulation at this stage is not the dominant regulatory mode, but relies more on platform autonomy and settled enterprises’ participation in the governance of platform ecosystems. This corresponds to the ESS point (0,1,1).
On this basis, the results of a 100-time evolution through the simulation of the self-renewal stage in the digital platform ecosystem are shown in
Figure 10. The three-dimensional evolution results show that in the maturity stage, the model’s layout stability point is (0,1,1); that is, in this stage, the platform tends to self-governance, settled enterprises tend to participate, and the government tends to not govern, which is consistent with the conclusion in
Figure 9.
7. Discussion
This study uses the evolutionary game method to analyze the governance methods and effects of different life cycle digital platform ecosystems from the perspective of a digital economy network. In this study, three dimensions of government governance platform structure empowerment and platform relationship empowerment were selected to reveal the differences in the governance effects of external regulation and platform autonomy on platform issues, show the influence of different factors on platform governance, identify the best platform governance mode in different development stages, and propose policy suggestions to overcome obstacles and promote digital platform development.
First, digital platform ecosystems often rely on mandatory government regulation in the early developmental stages. Digital platform ecosystems have evolved from scratch. At the beginning of the platform ecosystem, the number of internal platform organizations and settled enterprises were small, and the operation of the platform ecosystem was still in the exploratory stage [
57,
58]. Most platform organizations and settled enterprises took a wait-and-see attitude and did not act. At this time, government departments continued to formulate and improve relevant regulations and impose mandatory constraints for the platform ecosystem’s orderly operation [
54]. It can be seen from the research that in the formative period, the constraint effects of platform organizations and settled enterprises are not obvious, and only government supervision is effective. On the one hand, in the early stages, the rational autonomy mechanism of platform organization has not been formed, and settled enterprises have also come into contact with this emerging model; the legal awareness and rights protection channel is not perfect. On the other hand, government regulation of the platform and settled enterprises is stricter. Therefore, in a platform’s early stage, government plays a greater role in guiding, restraining, and helping the platform ecosystem to follow good governance.
Second, with greater ecosystem development, governments, platforms organization, and settled enterprises all come to play an important role in platform regulation. It has entered a period of expansion and leadership. These two stages are processes in which the scale of the platform organization continues to steadily expand. The research shows that in this stage, the constraint effect of platform organizations and settled enterprises gradually emerges. Specifically, in the expansion period, the constraint effect of platform organization gradually increases, and in the leadership period, the constraint effect of settled enterprises becomes more obvious, and even tends to overtake that of the platform. This may be because, with the ecosystem’s continuous maturation, the platform’s own governance and development mechanisms are also constantly rebuilt and improved, which produces a set of effective methods to deal with the problems encountered in development [
59]. At the same time, platform settled enterprises’ awareness of their rights has also steadily increased. Through continuous experimentation, effective and reasonable safeguards are formed; through the word-of-mouth effect, the platform’s non-compliant behaviors have become restrained [
60]. At this time, the government, platform organization, and settled enterprises impose joint constraints.
Third, at the last stage, the common constraints of platform organizations and settled enterprises prevail, and compulsory government regulation is weakened. In the self-renewal stage, owing to technological or market changes, platforms encounter the need for fundamental renewal. The search for new alternatives must begin before this point. In other words, perception is a continuous process [
44]. At this time, the platform ecosystem’s autonomy and consumer supervision play major roles, while the government’s supervision effect gradually weakens. This shows that with further platform development, if the platform wants to thrive and resist market elimination, it must rely on its strong governance mechanism, cooperating with consumer supervision. At this stage, the government’s compulsory supervision is gradually withdrawn as a primary constraint.
8. Implications
The drive toward digital platformization has gained significant impetus over the past decade. However, it is still a contradictory process, causing serious problems such as platform monopolies. This study provides some theoretical and practical contributions.
8.1 Theoretical implications
This study enriches the research on platform governance. Previous studies on platform governance have somewhat considered it from the perspective of the government, through legislation, subsidies, fines, and other mandatory ways to govern the platform [
61,
62]; however, from the governance effect perspective, they cannot fundamentally address the problem of platform development. In addition to government governance, this study introduces the perspective of platform autonomy to analyze platform self-governance using empowerment. This study discusses the platform embedded in the digital economy network and relies on the advantages of network structure and network relationships to empower small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) on the platform, thus serving the growth and development of SMEs to the maximum extent, forming a benign platform ecosystem, and realizing the sustainable development of the platform.
This study studies platform empowerment from the perspective of a digital economy network. Previous studies have focused on the important role of platform empowerment in the development of the platform itself and the growth of SMEs on the platform [
63,
64]. Platform empowerment provides more autonomy to the platform and enterprises so that enterprises can achieve the development of the platform while realizing their development. Based on the digital economy network, combined with the actual situation of the development of the digital economy, and relying on the perspective of the network, this study divides platform empowerment into two dimensions: structural empowerment and relational empowerment, further refining the specific impact mechanism of platform empowerment and enriching the research on platform empowerment to a certain extent.
This study expands the research on the life cycle of the platform ecosystem. Previous studies on platform governance rarely consider the platform lifecycle and ignore the particularity of different stages of platform development [
39], which will inevitably deviate from the effectiveness of platform governance. This study combined the life cycle theory with the platform governance theory and divided the platform life cycle into start-up, explosion, leadership, and maturity periods. Additionally, the platform governance mechanism under different life cycles was studied in detail to further improve the research on the platform life cycle.
8.2 Practical implications
This study also provides practical implications for the government and platform managers. First, the government should strengthen the supervision and governance of the platform. Research shows that government regulation plays an important role in the early stages of platform development. The government can identify and regulate anti-monopoly through price mechanisms and competition effects. The government should focus on the construction of a reasonable platform supervision system, particularly when the development of the platform is imperfect, to formulate corresponding supporting rules and institutional explanations for the system and policy supply to make the implementation of laws and regulations more accurate and scenario-oriented. Simultaneously, the government must innovate the big data supervision path, use the Internet, artificial intelligence, big data, and other technologies to empower platform supervision, prevent platform enterprises from performing exploitative pricing and damaging the overall social welfare of settled enterprises through data monopoly, data abuse, and other behaviors, and establish a new intelligent supervision system with multi-department coordination and multi-level unified command.
Second, platform autonomy has become an important part of the chain of supervision. The types and tools of the platform itself to exercise the regulatory functions are numerous and complex, and the self-governance of the platform focuses on the needs of the platform’s survival, such as consumer rights protection, intellectual property protection, consumer dispute settlement, transaction credit maintenance, and correct value orientation. The government should propose requirements for the platforms to clarify what problems the platforms should manage themselves, and the platforms should be able to express to the government and society the effectiveness of their internal compliance management and accept supervision.
Third, the government should vigorously promote the construction of a digital economy, accelerate the construction of a digital economy network framework, create a good digital ecology, promote the deep integration of traditional industries and digital technologies, and build a digital economy network with the platform as the core. The development of digital technology can further promote the integration of data and reality, and through the use of digital technology to perform all-round and whole-chain transformations of traditional industries, it can effectively improve total factor productivity and promote the digital, networking, and intelligent development of traditional industries. In the process of digital transformation of traditional industries, beginning in various fields, building a digital economy service platform for industry, society, and other fields, fully utilizing information and resources provided by major information and data exchange platforms, and strengthening the platform-based economic network can provide several opportunities for the development of SMEs to promote the development of new forms of the digital economy.