1. Introduction
Risk in financial and actuarial applications is sometimes defined as a random variable (r.v.) associated with costs or losses. Capital allocation problems arise when a total amount associated with the aggregate risk has to be distributed across the multiple units of risk that make it up. Examples of capital allocation problems can be found, for instance, in asset allocation strategies for portfolio selection, the allocation of the total solvency capital requirement across business lines or when distributing total claims administration costs among policies in the portfolio, among others.
A capital allocation principle is a set of guidelines that indicates how the total amount must be allocated. There is an extensive amount of capital allocation principles proposed in the literature. Some capital allocation principles have been motivated based on game theory in which capital allocation problems are interpreted as coalition games. In that context, the Aumann–Shapley value is one of the most popular capital allocation rules [
2,
3,
4,
5]. An alternative approach to derive capital allocation principles emerges from the economy theory. Capital allocation problems are interpreted as optimization problems in which a loss function of particular interest for risk managers is minimized [
6,
7,
8,
9]. Under this second approach, Dhaene et al. [
1] provided a unified theoretical framework in which a capital allocation principle is the outcome of a particular optimization problem. This framework was later generalized by Zaks and Tsanakas [
10] considering a hierarchical corporate structure at two organizational levels. More recently, Cai and Wang [
11] considered different loss functions for capital shortfall risk and capital surplus risk when allocating capital among business lines in the hierarchical corporate structure.
In the optimization setting proposed by Dhaene et al. [
1], the optimization problem has a unique solution when the quadratic optimization criterion is followed. The solution of the quadratic allocation criterion is derived via a geometric proof. In this article we provide an alternative proof of the solution to the quadratic allocation problem based on the Lagrangian method. To our knowledge, this proof has not been previously provided in the literature. Dhaene et al. [
1] and Zaks and Tsanakas [
10] followed geometric approaches to obtain solutions to their quadratic optimization problems. On the other hand, Cai and Wang [
11] used the Lagrangian method, but their optimization problem was based on the absolute allocation criterion. That is, their loss function was based on absolute deviations, allowing for different weighting functions to apply to positive and negative deviations.
A second contribution here is that we accommodate the haircut allocation principle into the capital allocation setting provided by Dhaene et al. [
1]. Most of capital allocation principles used in practice can be accommodated to the framework proposed by Dhaene et al. [
1]. However, the haircut allocation principle did not seem to be reconcilable with their general framework (Table 1 in[
1]). The haircut allocation principle has been widely used in the industry due to its simplicity [
12]. Under the haircut allocation principle, the portion of the aggregate capital allocated to a risk unit is computed as the proportion that the Value-at-Risk (VaR) associated to this risk unit represents in relation to the sum of VaR’s for all risk units. In this paper, we prove that the haircut allocation principle can be accommodated into the quadratic optimization criterion by relaxing one of the original conditions of Dhaene et al. [
1] . The general optimization framework of Dhaene et al. [
1] depends on a set of non-negative auxiliary random variables with expected value equal to one which are used as weight factors to the (scaled) deviations between losses and allocated risk capitals. Previously, Belles-Sampera et al. [
13] suggested a mechanism to accommodate the haircut allocation principle into the quadratic optimization framework by allowing auxiliary random variables to take negative values. However, as appointed by Cai and Wang [
11], when the auxiliary random variables take negative values the loss function could be concave and the optimization problem may not have minimizers. In addition, the proof of Proposition 1 of Belles-Sampera et al. [
13] was based on Theorem 1 of Dhaene et al. [
1], which can be only applied with non-negative auxiliary random variables with expected value equal to one. Inspired by Belles-Sampera et al. [
13], we here define a particular form of the auxiliary random variables from which the haircut allocation principle is derived. We show that the solution exits and it is unique. So, we demonstrate that the haircut allocation principle can be understood as the solution of a quadratic optimization problem. Finally, two particular examples are provided where the haircut allocation principle is obtained. The paper is structured as follows. The general optimal capital allocation framework is defined in the next section and the proof of the solution of the quadratic allocation criterion via the Lagrangian method is showed.
Section 3 provides the steps to accommodate the haircut allocation principle in this framework, as the solution to a quadratic optimization problem. Two examples are provided in
Section 4.
Section 5 concludes.
2. Risk capital allocation as a quadratic optimization problem
Assume that a capital
has to be allocated across
n business units denoted by
. The random variable
with finite expectation refers to the loss associated with the
business. According to [
1] (see Remark 2), most capital allocation problems can be described as the optimization problem given by
with the following characterizing elements:
- (a)
a function ;
- (b)
a set of positive values , ; and
- (c)
a set of random variables such that , .
If
is selected then the optimization criterion in (
1) is called the
quadratic optimization criterion.
Proposition 2.
The solution of the minimization problem proposed in the general framework defined in (1) under the quadratic optimization criterion is
Proof of Proposition 1. Let rewrite expression (
1) when
in the following way:
Now, let
and
for all
, so
for all
j. The expression (
3) can be rewritten as
Note that
is a random variable, while
is a constant. A similar procedure inspired in the proof of Theorem 1 by Dhaene et al. [
1] is followed. Let consider that,
The last two elements do not depend on
. So, the minimization problem in (
4) is equivalent to
Following a similar strategy to Zaks et al. [
8], the notation
is introduced
1. Note that
so, the optimization problem (5) is equivalent to
The selected method to solve problem (6) is the Lagrange multipliers’ method. Consider the Lagrangian function
The partial derivatives of function
with respect to
and
are
From equaling the first partial derivative (7) to zero, we obtain
Then,
and from (8) equal to zero, we obtain
and substituting in (9),
The objective function and constraints in (6) are convex functions, so the solution is unique. Changing notation from (6) to (5), then (10) can be expressed as
□
A proof that solution
in (10) is a minimum is provided. The bordered Hessian matrix of
,
is:
The characteristics of
matrix do not depend neither on
nor on
. The point
with
for all
i,
, is a minimum if all minors
of
have sign equal to
for
. As it is shown in the
Appendix A,
are equal to:
So, it is satisfied that for all , because for all due to for all j. Therefore, is a minimum in (6).
An alternative proof is given by Dhaene et al. [
1]. Authors indicate that problem (6) can be understood as finding the closest point to the origin that belongs to the hyperplane
So, the solution in (10) is unique and a minimum.
Remark 1. The proof of the Proposition 1 requires that , . This is satisfied with conditions (b) and (c). However, a more general framework may be defined with the conditions (b) and (c) expressed as follows:
- (b)
a set of weights , ; and
- (c)
a set of random variables , , with .
and the proof of the proposition still holds. However, the interpretation of a negative weight and a negative expected value of in the context of risk management is not as straightforward as with positive values.
Remark 2. The original allocation problem proposed by Dhaene et al. [1] considered (b) and (c) in (1) as follows,
- (b)
a set of non-negative weights , , such that ; and
- (c)
a set of non-negative random variables , , with .
Under these constraints, solution (2) can be simplified as,
3. Haircut allocation principle
In this section it is showed that the haircut allocation principle can be accommodated into the capital allocation setting (
1).
The haircut allocation principle is defined as follows. If a capital
has to be allocated across
n business units, the haircut allocation principle states that the capital
assigned to each business unit is
where
is the random loss linked to the
ith-business unit,
is the inverse of the cumulative distribution function of
and
is a given confidence level.
To accommodate the haircut allocation principle into (
1), we first introduce the following lemma.
Lemma 2.
Consider a constant and two random variables X and Y such that , , and . Let us define ζ as,
which satisfies
- a)
, and
- b)
.
Proof of Lemma 1 Taking expectations in (13),
Now, the numerator of
is multiplied by
X,
The expectation of the previous expression is,
Therefore, it holds that:
□
Remark 3.
The r.v. ζ defined in (13) may take non-positive values. Note that values of ζ lie on the straight line:
where
If , the intersection of the line with the horizontal axis, , is given by
Therefore, there are four scenarios in which ζ takes non-positive values depending on the value taken by Y. The four scenarios are summarized in Table 1.
Let us consider the following proposition.
Proposition 2. The three characterizing elements required to represent the haircut allocation principle (12) in the general framework defined by (3) are:
- (a)
,
- (b)
, ; and
- (c)
where is a random variable such that , for all .
Proof of Proposition 2 By Lemma 1,
and
for all
i, so the general solution (
2) is equal to,
which is the haircut allocation principle (12). □
Remark 4. Note that the condition is implicitly assumed in Proposition 2 to obtain well-defined weights . In fact, the equivalent condition is implicitly required to apply the haircut allocation principle (12).
4. Examples of in the haircut allocation
In this section two examples of random variable Y that could be used in the definition of in Proposition 2 to obtain the haircut allocation principle are provided.
Example 1.
Suppose that and for all . If , then is defined as follows to represent the haircut allocation principle (16) in the general framework defined by (1):
Proof of Example 1. Intuitively, we can state that r.v.
satisfies the necessary conditions stated in Lemma (1) because
, due to the assumption that
, and also because
(a detailed proof is provided in the
Appendix B). So,
By Lemma 1, it holds that:
Taking into account these results and assumptions of Proposition 2, the solution of the problem (
1) given by expression (
2) is the haircut allocation principle (12). □
Some remarks can be made in relation to Example 1.
Remark 5. Conditions for all are often read as ‘random variable has a bounded risk at α confidence level’ . In addition, considering that positive values of represent losses, if then there is no risk of loss for the ith random variable at α confidence level.
Remark 6. Example 1 accommodates the haircut allocation principle in (almost) the original framework of Dhaene et al. [1]. This ‘almost’ is for those cases in which and also because in Example 1 is not restricted to be a positive random variable.
An additional example of a random variable satisfying conditions of Proposition 2 is provided.
Example 2.
Suppose is a non-negative r.v. with finite variance () for . The r.v is defined as , then expression of is:
Note that because the variance is greater than zero.
Remark 7. According to Dhaene et al. [1], a proportional capital allocation principle is a ‘business unit driven proportional allocation principle’ when depends on , and an ‘aggregate portfolio driven proportional allocation principle’ when depends on , for . Under this classification the haircut allocation principle defined in Proposition 2 is a ‘business unit driven proportional allocation principle.’ Let suposse is equal to S for all i in the definition of . Since the r.v. S can be mathematically dependent of in some cases, the haircut allocation principle would be classified as ‘business unit driven proportional allocation principle’ and also ‘aggregate portfolio driven proportional allocation principle,’ which seems counter-intuitive. Here, we propose to define a ‘aggregate portfolio driven’ as follows: and must depend on S. Now, the haircut allocation principle is a ‘business unit driven proportional allocation principle’ but not a ‘aggregate portfolio driven proportional allocation principle.’
5. Conclusions
In this paper we generalize the capital allocation framework proposed by Dhaene et al. [
1]. We prove that the haircut capital allocation principle can now be accommodated in that general optimization framework. Under this general capital allocation setting, we provide an alternative and interpretable form to obtain the optimal solution to the quadratic optimization problem that complements the existing geometrical proof. All required steps to obtain the optimal solution to that capital allocation framework are described in order to be easy to follow by a broad (not necessarily expert) audience. We argue that the majority of relevant scenarios from a risk management perspective can be represented in our capital allocation framework.
Author Contributions
Conceptualization, methodology, validation, investigation, writing and editing, J.B.S., M.G and M.S. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.
Funding
The Spanish Ministry of Science and Innovation supported this study under the grant PID2019-105986GB-C21.
Conflicts of Interest
The authors declare no conflict of interest.’
Appendix A
Let
,
, be the determinant in expression (11). We want to show that
We propose a proof by induction. Starting from
,
Now, let us assume that
. In this case, note that
Appendix B
This appendix proves that
defined in Example 1 satisfies that
,
. Note it holds that
and
. Therefore,
satisfies
is equivalent to prove that:
Let us rewrite the previous inequality as,
Now, two cases are considered: and .
Case :
Following Belles-Sampera et al. [
14] and Denuit et al. [
15],
is equal to,
Therefore, expression (A1) can be represented as:
which is positive. The last inequality holds because
,
,
and
for all
. □
Case : is equal to:
Expression (A1) can be now represented as:
The last inequality holds because , , and for all . □
References
- Dhaene, J.; Tsanakas, A.; Valdez, E.A.; Vanduffel, S. Optimal Capital Allocation Principles. Journal of Risk and Insurance 2012, 79, 1–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Denault, M. Coherent allocation of risk capital. Journal of Risk 2001, 4, 1–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tsanakas, A.; Barnett, C. Risk capital allocation and cooperative pricing of insurance liabilities. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 2003, 33, 239–254. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Boonen, T.J. t-value for risk capital allocation problems. Operations Research Letters 2020, 48, 752–757. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tsanakas, A. To split or not to split: Capital allocation with convex risk measures. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 2009, 44, 268–277. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Furman, E.; Zitikis, R. Weighted risk capital allocations. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 2008, 43, 263–269. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dhaene, J.; Goovaerts, M.; Kaas, R. Economic Capital Allocation Derived from Risk Measures. North American Actuarial Journal 2003, 7, 44–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zaks, Y.; Frostig, E.; Levikson, B. Optimal pricing of a heterogeneous portfolio for a given risk level. ASTIN Bulletin 2006, 36, 161–185. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- van Gulick, G.; De Waegenaere, A.; Norde, H. Excess based allocation of risk capital. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 2012, 50, 26–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zaks, Y.; Tsanakas, A. Optimal capital allocation in a hierarchical corporate structure. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 2014, 56, 48–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cai, J.; Wang, Y. Optimal capital allocation principles considering capital shortfall and surplus risks in a hierarchical corporate structure. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 2021, 100, 329–349. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- McNeil, A.J.; Frey, R.; Embrechts, P. Quantitative Risk Management: Concepts, Techniques and Tools. Princeton University Press, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Belles-Sampera, J.; Guillen, M.; Santolino, M. GlueVaR risk measures in capital allocation applications. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 2014, 58, 132–137. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Belles-Sampera, J.; Guillen, M.; Santolino, M. Risk Quantification and Allocation Methods for Practitioners. Amsterdam University Press, 2017. [Google Scholar]
- Denuit, M.; Dhaene, J.; Goovaerts, M.; Kaas, R. Actuarial Theory for Dependent Risks. Measures, Orders and Models.; John Wiley & Sons Ltd: Chichester, 2005. [Google Scholar]
1 |
Note that is properly defined since . |
Table 1.
Scenarios that r.v.
defined in (
13) takes non-positive values.
Table 1.
Scenarios that r.v.
defined in (
13) takes non-positive values.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2023 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).