2. Control of an Emerging Disease
In the study of epidemic control, effective management of a disease spread is crucial, particularly at the onset of an outbreak. While the importance of vaccination in fighting infectious diseases is undeniable, it takes time to develop a vaccine for an emerging strain. Various parameters including environmental factors, immunity patterns, and behavioral changes impact the circulation of a virus. Social distancing and personal hygiene measures (non-medical interventions) play an important role in containing the disease at an early ascending stage. By optimizing the implementation of non-medical interventions over time the effectiveness of these interventions can be increased.
Another essential component of control and prevention is treatment with antiviral medications, which allows to reduce the period of infectiousness and/or reduce the disease fatality rate. To account for these two important types of control, we consider the following
(Susceptible-Infectious-Removed) model [
17] for early disease transmission:
In system (
1), we assume that individuals who have recovered from the disease gain immunity for the duration of the study and do not return to the susceptible class,
. Additionally, we assume that natural birth and death rates balance one another and the removed class,
, contains individuals who recovered from the disease and those who died. The two disease parameters,
and
are transmission and recovery rates, respectively.
The focus of this research is on introducing optimal controls during initial weeks of a pandemic in order to delay and reduce the daily number of infections. This approach enables health centers and decision-making organizations to implement more effective operations. In what follows, we incorporate two different kinds of control in
model [
18] resulting in the system
, where
Here
,
, and
are normalized susceptible, infected and removed compartments, respectively, and
N is the population of the region at the beginning of the study period. The function
represents nonmedical controls (social distancing, remote work, online education, restriction on travel, lockdowns, etc.), while
stands for treatment with antiviral medications and other medical interventions. A positive parameter,
, is the efficacy of antiviral treatments [
19]. In the above,
,
, and the admissible set for each control function is
In (
2), the first control,
, aims to change the disease transmission rate from
to
while the second control,
, is expected to reduce the period of infectiousness, which is
in the initial system (
1). In combination, the two controls,
and
, are meant to minimize the force of infection,
, while keeping the costs at bay. The costs are considered in a general sense, which includes a negative impact on mental health, education, economy and on overall quality of life.
In Lemma 2.1 below we show that following the introduction of a time-dependent transmission rate,
, and a time-dependent recovery rate,
, the model
in (
2) remains well-defined in the sense that the state variables,
originating in a positive octant do not leave the octant for all values of
. The proof of this lemma is similar to the argument in [
20], where system (
2) was considered with nonmedical controls only (that is,
).
Lemma 2.1 [
20].
Let , be admissible control trajectories with satisfying given by (2) and the probability simplex in . Then for all .
Note that the argument in [
20] implies that the conclusion of Lemma 2.1 is not limited to
and
. It is valid for any integrable nonnegative functions
and
. To optimize the implementation of both controls,
and
, we consider the following objective functional
According to system (
2), one can integrate the first term to obtain
where
is the assumed cost of control and
,
, is the regularization parameter (weight). As our numerical experiments show, the choice of the cost function,
, significantly influences the resulting control strategy. From practical standpoint, neither
nor
should take negative values. At the same time, the cost,
, must increase dramatically as
approaches 1, the upper bound of the feasible set (
3), since it is impossible to entirely eliminate the disease transmission
. It is equally impossible to reach full capacity of antiviral treatment (
) due to limitations of testing and other factors. Therefore, in our approach we impose the following assumptions on the cost functions,
and
[
20]:
These assumptions on the cost of control were first proposed in [
20] for a special case when
. The authors of [
20] employed the techniques of machine learning to show that under assumptions (
5), the global minimum of the Hamiltonian gives rise to the optimal control strategy,
, which stays within the feasible set (
3) for all values of
. Assumptions (
5) are the alternative to a more traditional cost function,
, that is often used in control literature. However,
does not, generally, prevent the global minimum from becoming greater than 1 for some values of
t, even for large weights,
3. Theoretical Study and Discussion
In this section we state and prove our main theoretical result.
Theorem 3.1.
Let be an optimal control strategy with respect to the objective functional defined in (4) and biological model , , introduced in (2), with satisfying (5) and , . Then there is such that for any , the derivative, , exists and . In other words, there is such that for any , both optimal controls, and , are decreasing.
Proof. According to the Pontryagin’s Minimum Principle [
21,
22], if
is an optimal control with respect to the objective functional
and the system
,
, then there is a trajectory
such that
By the properties (
5) of the cost,
, one has
for
and
, which prevents any
,
,
from being the optimal of
with respect to
at any time
. Therefore, the Karush–Kuhn–Tucker (KKT) conditions for the optimal control problem (
2), (
3), (
4) take the form
As it follows from (
2), (
4), and (
7),
which yields
To show that on some
the derivative,
, exists and
, we follow [
20]. Conditions (K2) and (K3) imply that
is differentiable and therefore continuous for any
. From Lemma 2.1, one concludes that
as long as
and
are positive. On the other hand, since
, there is
such that
for all
. Suppose at some point
, the Lagrange multiplier,
, is greater than zero. Then from (K4) it follows that
. By (
5), this implies
, which means that in (
14)
, while
. Hence, we arrive at the contradiction. Therefore, for any
, one has
and
. By implicit function theorem, for
the derivative,
, exists and
Taking into consideration (
2), (
4), and (
7), one obtains
Furthermore, from (
4) one gets
. This together with (16) implies that
and the costate equations for
and
take the form:
Combining (
2) and (17), one can rewrite
as follows
From (24) and (15), one concludes
Since
and
,
,
for
, there exists
such that
and
for all
. Let
, then
is negative in
As noted above,
, therefore identity (14) yields
Taking into account (17), one arrives at
Integrating (21) from
t to
T and substituting
, one gets
As shown above,
is negative on
. Thus (
3) and (22) imply that
for all
. Using the same argument as in the case of
, one can now conclude that
in (20) is equal to zero on
, that is, the constraint
is not active for
and
. By implicit function theorem, for
the derivative,
, exists and
From (
2) and (17) one has
since
for all
and
. This implies
in
, which completes the proof. □
Remark 3.2 By (
5) and (
7),
. Therefore,
is positive definite and
has a unique global minimum with respect to
. From the proof of Theorem 3.1, it follows that both coordinates of the global minimum,
and
, are guaranteed to be less than 1, pointwisely, but they are not guaranteed to be greater than 0 necessarily, which means the solution to our optimal control problem can be a local minimum rather than global. The reason the coordinates of the global minimum,
,
, can potentially be less than zero for some values of
t is that, counterintuitively, a smaller effective reproduction number,
, in the SIR model does not always imply a smaller cumulative number of infected people,
. Hence, even though for system (
2), the effective reproduction number,
, goes down with more control, it does not guarantee that
yields
for every value of
t. One can, however, show that if
and
is non-increasing, then
. This result is important in its own right. Its proof is given in Appendix.
Remark 3.3 Despite the fact that, theoretically, the solution to our optimal control problem can be a local minimum rather than global, in all numerical experiments presented in the next section, the optimal strategy is a unique global minimum. In other words, in all our experiments, the optimal control has been computed from the first-order necessary condition for unconstrained minimization, and nonnegativity constraints held without being enforced. For all cost functions,
, satisfying (
5), the global minimum of
with respect to
has nonnegative coordinates,
,
. That is,
is equivalent to
for all
This illustrates that conditions (
5) lead to a practically justified mitigation scenario. Numerical simulations have also confirmed, as proven in Theorem 3.1, that both controls,
and
, are decreasing toward the end of the study period.
4. Numerical Experiments
In our numerical study, we use a second-order trust-region algorithm for nonlinear optimization ’lsqnonlin’ combined with ode15s built-in function to approximate the solution to optimal control problem (
4) subject to compartmental model (
2) and costate system (17). For every value of
, we solve system (
2) forward in time (starting with
), to get
using ode15s. Then system (17) is solved back in time by ode15s to obtain
. Given
, we find
by applying a second-order trust-region ’lsqnonlin’ algorithm.
Following [
20], we consider three different cost functions,
,
, and
satisfying conditions (
5):
In (26), the coefficients are chosen to minimize the weighted distance [
20]
The cost of control,
,
, and
, is infinite as
u approaches its ultimate value, 1. For comparison, we also use the cost function
, for which (
5) does not hold. The cost function
is popular in applications of control theory in epidemiology and other fields, since for this function the first order optimality condition is linear with respect to
u. This is a useful property that simplifies numerical algorithms. However, the cost of control,
, is finite at
, which is not realistic in real-world scenarios.
Figure 4 and
Figure 7 show that the global minimum,
, of the Hamiltonian,
, does not stay in the range of
if the cost is given by
, especially for small values of
,
. Thus, an explicit constraint
must be imposed in the case of
. Even with the constraint
, the optimal control function,
, often reaches the ultimate level [
15],
, which is not practical.
In all numerical experiments presented in this section,
,
. Therefore, moving forward, we omit the first index and set
. Comparison of the four cost functions in the interval
is illustrated in
Figure 1.
In this study, numerical simulations are conducted for and equal to , , , and . Three different scenarios are explored. First, there is only non-medical control, , (social distancing, behavioral changes, hand washing, etc.) in the system and treatment with antiviral medications, , is not available. Second, only control , treatment with antiviral medications, is applied; no social distancing. And third, controls and , medical and non-medical, are used in combination. In our experiments, the population of the region, N, is assumed to be . The initial number of infected individuals on day 1 is 200, and the duration of the study period is 120 days. Transmission rate, , and recovery rate, , are assumed to be , and , respectively, leading to the basic reproduction number . The efficacy of antiviral medication, , is assumed to be when applicable.
4.1. Scenario 1: Social Distancing Control Only
In the first scenario, only one (non-medical) control,
, is applied (
Figure 2,
Figure 3, and
Figure 4). As one can see in the figures, when the weight of control,
, increases, the effectiveness of control goes down; see also
Table 1 that illustrates how
changes over time for the cost
with different values of
(find similar Tables for
,
, and
in the Appendix). One can conclude from
Figure 2 that control
works by eliminating some cases but also by delaying some of them. Therefore, even though the cumulative number of infections in the controlled environment is significantly less than in the environment with no control, towards the end of the study period the daily number of infected individuals in the controlled environment may be higher.
Figure 2,
Figure 3, and
Figure 4 with
equal to
,
, and
, respectively, show the pattern of
decreasing as the values of
go down. Based on these figures and
Table 1, the "flattening of the curve" is evident.
4.2. Scenario 2: Control with Antiviral Medication Only
For the next set of experiments, it was assumed that there is only control
in the system. In
Figure 5,
Figure 6,
Figure 7, one can see the effect of the weight,
, on different cost functions and, as the result, on state variables
,
, and
over time. Again, as the weight,
, decreases the control plays a more effective role in reducing the number of infected people (See
Table 2,
Table A16,
Table A17, and
Table A18 for more details).
Overall, the effects of controls
and
on the system, when only one control is applied, are similar. However, as one can clearly see from
Table 3, for the same cost and over the same time interval, control
suppresses infections more aggressively than
. Also, there is a significant difference between the results for cost function
and the rest of the cost functions. While for
,
, and
the maximum number of infected people on any given day in the case of "first control only" is
, this number is
for
. Additionally, in the case of "second control only", the maximum daily number of infected individuals for
exceeds the maximum daily number for other cost functions by
cases. The best performance among all cost functions can be attributed to
in both cases where only control
or only control
is applied. For details, one can see
Table 3 and
Figure 8.
4.3. Scenario 3: Non-Medical and Medical Controls in Combination
For the next step, we apply two controls to the
system,
and
, together with the same weights,
, in order to evaluate their effect on the outbreak (See
Figure 9,
Figure 10, and
Figure 11). As expected, in terms of its dependence on
, the combination of two controls,
and
, behaves pretty similar to the case of one control in a sense that when the weight,
, decreases, the controls become more effective, and the daily number of infected humans goes down.
Table 4 and
Table 5 show the daily number of infected individuals,
, and the cumulative number of infected individuals up to day
t,
, for different control scenarios. This gives an insight into how the two controls,
and
, compare individually and in combination subject to the same cost,
, and the same weight,
.
Table 5 illustrates that the cumulative number of infections after applying both controls for 120 days is
, while the "no control" counterpart is
. And in the case of control with antiviral medication,
, after 120 days there are more than 3 times fewer cases as compared to the case of social distancing control,
(
vs.
). Similar tables related to the cost functions
,
, and
can be found in Appendix (
Table A1 -
Table A6).
In the next series of experiments, controls
and
have different weights,
and
, applied to their respective cost functions. We consider two cases. First, for the cost function
, the weight of control
is less than the weight of control
(
).
Table 6 shows changes in daily numbers of infected people,
, for the cost function
, in the case of fixed weight (
) for control
and different weights for control
(
Table A7 -
Table A9 for cost functions
, and
can be found in Appendix). As it follows from
Table 6, adding the second control,
, with any weight,
, helps to better contain the outbreak and to decrease the daily number of infected people and the cumulative number of cases. Even for high effort case of
, the number of daily infections is
cases less than the daily number of infected individuals in case when there is no control
. However, when the weight of the second control,
, increases, the effort required to implement that measure also rises, making it increasingly challenging to execute.
If the roles are reversed, that is, for the cost function
, the weight,
, of the second control,
, is fixed and the sensitivity of the system to the first control,
, is observed, the pattern is similar. Namely, adding a non-medical control,
, reduces the daily number of infected people. Even though it is not as consequential as in the case when control
is added, still there are fewer infected people in all cases with two controls as opposed to the case of
only. At the same time, it is evident that the second control,
, is more efficient. Indeed, for the high effort case of
, the number of daily infections is only
cases less than the daily number of infected individuals in case when there is no control
(as opposed to
reduction when
was added with the same effort,
). The difference in the daily number of infected individuals between the case of no
(i.e.,
only with weight
) and the case of
with
and
with varying weights ranges from
to
. See
Table 7,
Table A10,
Table A11, and
Table A12 for more details.
Figure 13 and
Figure 14 show the behavior of controls and their effect on the graphs of
for different cost functions and different weights. As it is evident from the graphs, when
and
, the second control,
, is dominant and very efficient. At the same time, when
and
, the two controls,
and
, are about the same, and there are more infected people towards the end of the study period, that is, the control strategy in
Figure 14 is less efficient as compared to the case of
Figure 13. The two figures, once again, underline the significance of the second control,
.
Figure 1.
Comparison of the four control cost functions used in numerical experiments below: , , .
Figure 1.
Comparison of the four control cost functions used in numerical experiments below: , , .
Figure 2.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and control (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight is .
Figure 2.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and control (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight is .
Figure 3.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and control (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight is .
Figure 3.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and control (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight is .
Figure 4.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and control (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight is . For the cost function , stays above the ultimate value, , for more than half of the study period, which is not practical.
Figure 4.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and control (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight is . For the cost function , stays above the ultimate value, , for more than half of the study period, which is not practical.
Figure 5.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and control (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight is .
Figure 5.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and control (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight is .
Figure 6.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and control (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight is .
Figure 6.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and control (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight is .
Figure 7.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and control (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight is .
Figure 7.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and control (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight is .
Figure 8.
Graphs of for different cost functions when only is applied and (shown with solid lines), and when only is applied and (shown with dashed line).
Figure 8.
Graphs of for different cost functions when only is applied and (shown with solid lines), and when only is applied and (shown with dashed line).
Figure 9.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and controls shown with solid lines, and with dashed lines (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weights, , and , for both controls are .
Figure 9.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and controls shown with solid lines, and with dashed lines (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weights, , and , for both controls are .
Figure 10.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and control shown with solid lines, and with dashed lines (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight, , for both controls is .
Figure 10.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and control shown with solid lines, and with dashed lines (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight, , for both controls is .
Figure 11.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and controls shown with solid lines, and with dashed lines (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight, , for both controls is .
Figure 11.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and controls shown with solid lines, and with dashed lines (bottom on the right) over time for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight, , for both controls is .
Figure 12.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and controls shown with solid lines and with dashed lines (bottom on the right) for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight, , for both controls is . Control for cost function takes unrealistic values above 1 at the early period of the study.
Figure 12.
Graphs of Susceptible (top on the left), Infected (top on the right), Recovered (bottom on the left) people, and controls shown with solid lines and with dashed lines (bottom on the right) for four different cost functions versus No Control when weight, , for both controls is . Control for cost function takes unrealistic values above 1 at the early period of the study.
Figure 13.
The proportion of Infected people, , for different cost functions and No Control case when (on the top ) and controls shown with solid lines, and with dashed lines (on the bottom).
Figure 13.
The proportion of Infected people, , for different cost functions and No Control case when (on the top ) and controls shown with solid lines, and with dashed lines (on the bottom).
Figure 14.
The proportion of Infected people, , for different cost functions and No Control case when (on the top) and controls shown with solid lines, and with dashed lines (on the bottom).
Figure 14.
The proportion of Infected people, , for different cost functions and No Control case when (on the top) and controls shown with solid lines, and with dashed lines (on the bottom).
Table 1.
Comparison of for cost function in case when only control is applied and varies. As increases, the number of infected individuals, , gets higher on most days.
Table 1.
Comparison of for cost function in case when only control is applied and varies. As increases, the number of infected individuals, , gets higher on most days.
Day |
No 2nd Control |
No 2nd Control |
No 2nd Control |
No 2nd Control |
No Control |
1 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
10 |
85 |
253 |
315 |
387 |
1,237 |
20 |
34 |
329 |
527 |
812 |
9,228 |
30 |
15 |
432 |
880 |
1,691 |
67,606 |
40 |
7 |
571 |
1,466 |
3,514 |
456,639 |
50 |
4 |
761 |
2,447 |
7,267 |
1,985,292 |
60 |
3 |
1,028 |
4,089 |
14,927 |
2,987,989 |
70 |
2 |
1,416 |
6,873 |
30,388 |
2,015,872 |
80 |
1 |
2,003 |
11,678 |
61,024 |
1,023,788 |
90 |
1 |
2,953 |
20,264 |
120,429 |
474,813 |
100 |
1 |
4,643 |
36,661 |
233,756 |
213,085 |
110 |
1 |
8,190 |
72,008 |
453,110 |
94,393 |
120 |
1 |
18,714 |
174,758 |
922,708 |
41,578 |
Table 2.
Comparison of for cost function in case when only control is applied and varies. As increases, the number of infected individuals, , gets higher on most days.
Table 2.
Comparison of for cost function in case when only control is applied and varies. As increases, the number of infected individuals, , gets higher on most days.
Day |
No 1st Control |
No 1st Control |
No 1st Control |
No 1st Control |
No 1st Control |
No Control |
1 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
10 |
18 |
181 |
254 |
318 |
377 |
1,237 |
20 |
1 |
168 |
332 |
530 |
756 |
9,228 |
30 |
0 |
164 |
437 |
880 |
1,503 |
67,606 |
40 |
0 |
166 |
581 |
1,456 |
2,949 |
456,639 |
50 |
0 |
177 |
782 |
2,395 |
5,693 |
1,985,292 |
60 |
0 |
198 |
1,073 |
3,938 |
10,735 |
2,987,989 |
70 |
0 |
234 |
1,515 |
6,481 |
19,547 |
2,015,872 |
80 |
0 |
299 |
2,226 |
10,735 |
34,005 |
1,023,788 |
90 |
0 |
420 |
3,485 |
18,210 |
56,943 |
474,813 |
100 |
0 |
676 |
6,092 |
33,048 |
95,559 |
213,085 |
110 |
0 |
1,391 |
13,102 |
70,339 |
177,085 |
94,393 |
120 |
0 |
5,265 |
49,724 |
244,998 |
499,616 |
41,578 |
Table 3.
Comparison of for all cost functions in the case when only control is applied () or only control is applied () over time.
Table 3.
Comparison of for all cost functions in the case when only control is applied () or only control is applied () over time.
Day |
No 2nd Control |
No 1st Control
|
No 2nd Control |
No 1st Control
|
No 2nd Control |
No 1st Control
|
No 2nd Control |
No 1st Control
|
|
|
|
|
|
1 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
10 |
387 |
318 |
388 |
317 |
377 |
308 |
401 |
349 |
20 |
812 |
530 |
816 |
527 |
766 |
495 |
918 |
644 |
30 |
1,691 |
880 |
1,706 |
872 |
1,552 |
795 |
2,133 |
1,178 |
40 |
3,514 |
1,456 |
3,557 |
1,439 |
3,134 |
1,273 |
4,939 |
2,133 |
50 |
7,267 |
2,395 |
7,379 |
2,362 |
6,302 |
2,034 |
11,366 |
3,816 |
60 |
14,927 |
3,938 |
15,209 |
3,879 |
12,618 |
3,258 |
25,851 |
6,733 |
70 |
30,388 |
6,481 |
31,076 |
6,381 |
25,120 |
5,256 |
57,953 |
11,672 |
80 |
61,024 |
10,735 |
6,2623 |
10,561 |
49,586 |
8,558 |
127,302 |
19,877 |
90 |
120,429 |
18,210 |
123,913 |
17,880 |
96,926 |
14,338 |
266,304 |
33,825 |
100 |
233,756 |
33,048 |
240,619 |
32,336 |
188,180 |
25,768 |
509,874 |
60,100 |
110 |
453,110 |
70,339 |
463,527 |
67,697 |
367,745 |
53,756 |
899,275 |
123,379 |
120 |
922,708 |
244,998 |
923,332 |
229,683 |
760,101 |
183,048 |
1,511,537 |
399,149 |
Table 4.
Comparison of for cost function when there is only , only , and both applied versus No Control case over time when .
Table 4.
Comparison of for cost function when there is only , only , and both applied versus No Control case over time when .
Day |
No Control |
No 2nd Control |
No 1st Control
|
|
1 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
10 |
1,237 |
387 |
318 |
300 |
20 |
9,228 |
812 |
530 |
472 |
30 |
67,606 |
1,691 |
880 |
743 |
40 |
456,639 |
3,514 |
1,456 |
1,167 |
50 |
1,985,292 |
7,267 |
2,395 |
1,834 |
60 |
2,987,989 |
14,927 |
3,938 |
2,897 |
70 |
2,015,872 |
30,388 |
6,481 |
4,625 |
80 |
1,023,788 |
61,024 |
10,735 |
7,522 |
90 |
474,813 |
120,429 |
18,210 |
12,727 |
100 |
213,085 |
233,756 |
33,048 |
23,355 |
110 |
94,393 |
453,110 |
70,339 |
50,792 |
120 |
41,578 |
922,708 |
244,998 |
173,543 |
Table 5.
Cumulative number of infections up to day t, for cost function when there is only , only , and both versus No Control case over time when weight .
Table 5.
Cumulative number of infections up to day t, for cost function when there is only , only , and both versus No Control case over time when weight .
Day |
No Control |
No 2nd Control |
No 1st Control
|
|
1 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
10 |
1,756 |
643 |
898 |
772 |
20 |
13,747 |
1,649 |
2,156 |
1,761 |
30 |
101,568 |
3,735 |
4,239 |
3,312 |
40 |
697,572 |
8,067 |
7,686 |
5,748 |
50 |
3,338,392 |
17,006 |
13,356 |
9,562 |
60 |
7,032,920 |
35,334 |
22,686 |
15,568 |
70 |
8,627,485 |
72,609 |
37,993 |
25,108 |
80 |
9,121,747 |
147,335 |
63,222 |
40,496 |
90 |
9,292,217 |
294,458 |
105,246 |
66,067 |
100 |
9,358,556 |
579,209 |
178,417 |
111,270 |
110 |
9,386,082 |
1,130,270 |
320,258 |
202,389 |
120 |
9,397,865 |
2,256,854 |
692,160 |
454,205 |
Table 6.
Comparison of the daily number of infected people, , for the cost function with the weight for . The weights for the control are , , , and for the second, third, and fourth columns, respectively, and the fifth column shows the case of No Control over time.
Table 6.
Comparison of the daily number of infected people, , for the cost function with the weight for . The weights for the control are , , , and for the second, third, and fourth columns, respectively, and the fifth column shows the case of No Control over time.
Day |
|
|
|
|
No 2nd Control |
1 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
10 |
180 |
251 |
300 |
321 |
387 |
20 |
167 |
323 |
472 |
545 |
812 |
30 |
163 |
421 |
743 |
925 |
1,691 |
40 |
165 |
554 |
1,167 |
1,561 |
3,514 |
50 |
175 |
737 |
1,834 |
2,629 |
7,267 |
60 |
195 |
1,002 |
2,897 |
4,428 |
14,927 |
70 |
231 |
1,404 |
4,625 |
7,481 |
30,388 |
80 |
291 |
2,049 |
7,522 |
12,748 |
61,024 |
90 |
403 |
3,188 |
12,727 |
22,274 |
120,429 |
100 |
646 |
5,554 |
23,355 |
41,465 |
233,756 |
110 |
1,306 |
11,909 |
50,792 |
89,010 |
453,110 |
120 |
4,879 |
44,363 |
173,543 |
280,668 |
922,708 |
Table 7.
Comparison of the daily number of infected people, , for the cost function with the weight for . The weights for the control are , , , and for the second, third, and fourth columns, respectively, and the fifth column shows the case of No Control over time.
Table 7.
Comparison of the daily number of infected people, , for the cost function with the weight for . The weights for the control are , , , and for the second, third, and fourth columns, respectively, and the fifth column shows the case of No Control over time.
Day |
|
|
|
|
No 1st Control
|
1 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
200 |
10 |
245 |
281 |
300 |
306 |
318 |
20 |
308 |
411 |
472 |
492 |
530 |
30 |
390 |
604 |
743 |
791 |
880 |
40 |
500 |
890 |
1,167 |
1,268 |
1,456 |
50 |
649 |
1,318 |
1,834 |
2,028 |
2,395 |
60 |
857 |
1,976 |
2,897 |
3,253 |
3,938 |
70 |
1,159 |
3,016 |
4,625 |
5,258 |
6,481 |
80 |
1,621 |
4,732 |
7,522 |
8,613 |
10,735 |
90 |
2,383 |
7,788 |
12,727 |
14,602 |
18,210 |
100 |
3,777 |
13,962 |
23,355 |
26,759 |
33,048 |
110 |
6,844 |
29,381 |
50,792 |
57,816 |
70,339 |
120 |
16,608 |
90,271 |
173,543 |
200,015 |
244,998 |