1. Introduction
Forest ecosystems provide numerous services that are essential for human well-being and welfare, characterized by intricate interconnections among forest ecosystem services (FESs) [
1]. Implementing sustainable forest management (SFM) policies demands an understanding of the trade-offs, conflicts, and synergies among key forest ecosystem services (FESs), highlighting the need for decision-support tools that can address multiple objectives [
2,
3].
The complex and heterogeneous nature of forest ecosystems has consistently presented challenges for effective forest planning and management. This has prompted researchers to seek optimal strategies for forest management. Optimization in this context may involve presenting general or specific solutions, expressed through numerical data and figures, and can be applied in both discrete and continuous dimensions of time and space [
4].
The Hyrcanian or Caspian forests of Iran, remnants of the broad-leaved forests of the Northern Hemisphere, are crucial for natural resource planning. These forests have decreased from 3.5 million has in 1964 to 1.9 million has, with a decline in quality and species diversity [
5]. Recent studies confirm the ongoing degradation, highlighting significant deforestation and biodiversity loss [
6].
Two main stakeholder groups are involved: local stakeholders focused on traditional livelihood and exploitation, and industrial stakeholders focused on wood production. The incompatible exploitation methods have led to a long-term decline in forest quantity and quality, conflicting with environmental goals aimed at forest protection [
1,
7,
8].
Differences in stakeholders' perspectives can be a potential source of conflict in forest management. Involving diverse stakeholders in policymaking is essential for effective natural resource management, particularly when there are varying management objectives. Such inclusion promotes more rational and efficient goal-setting, helping to achieve desired outcomes at lower costs. To reach consensus and make informed decisions, it is crucial to adopt methods that facilitate the collection and analysis of these diverse stakeholder opinions [
9]. The involvement of all stakeholders can increase the complexity and costs associated with the participatory process. Striking an optimal balance between these risks poses a significant challenge. However, the coalition and collaboration of all stakeholders are essential principles for ensuring successful participation [
10,
11]. The primary goal of optimal and sustainable forest management is to achieve a win-win solution that balances human well-being with the conservation of forest ecosystems. However, a significant challenge in pursuing this objective is the existing gap between the various stakeholders involved [
12].
In order to achieve a balance between the goal of economic profit increase, which is the aim of forest users (local people, stakeholders, forest dwellers, etc.), and the objective of reducing negative environmental impacts, which is the goal of policymakers, managers, and governmental management institutions (such as Forests, Rangelands and Watershed Management Organization, Environmental Organizations and Environmental NGOs), improvement in one goal comes at the expense of losing another [
13].
In this context, conventional optimization techniques can offer valuable insights into the strategic behavior of various stakeholders. In decision-making for managing forest economics, numerous methods have been employed, many of which utilize mathematical optimization approaches [
14]. One effective method for addressing conflicting situations is the use of multi-objective and game theory models. These models prioritize the overall system's interests rather than individual stakeholders' personal interests [
15].
The application of multi-objective planning methods in forestry commenced in the 1960s and remained an operational concept for nearly two decades [
16]. Since then, the focus has shifted towards the development of planning models capable of effectively managing multiple objectives, with increased emphasis on methods such as Linear Programming (LP) and Goal Programming (GP) [
17,
18]. Noteworthy studies in this area include those by [
19,
20,
21,
22,
23,
24,
25,
26].
A few studies have focused on deterministic techniques with more than two objectives in forest management planning [
27,
28,
29,
30,
31,
32]. All these studies implicitly assume that parameters are known in advance with certainty. However, in a few studies, which characterized by long-term planning nature, decision-makers face multiple uncertain parameters. This includes market parameters uncertainty (e.g., price and interest rate) and uncertainty in timber growth, yield and mortality which may be intensified by climate change [
3,
33,
34,
35,
36,
37,
38,
39].
Game theory finds application in forestry by analyzing strategic interactions among stakeholders, such as governments, forest owners, and environmental groups, to model decision-making processes and outcomes related to forest management and conservation policies. The insight provided by game theory can be a very useful guide for selecting, predicting, or understanding rational behavior under [
40]. This technique was first introduced by Neumann & Morgenstern (1944) [
41]. Nash proposed a new concept called "Nash equilibrium" in 1950 [
42]. Flåm studied "dynamic games" in 1990. Since then, game theory has been used in various sciences, including economics [
43], social sciences [
44], land use [
45], fire control [
46,
47], water resource management [
48,
49,
50,
51], timber market [
52,
53,
54], paper market [
33], forest management [
55,
56] watershed management [
21,
57] and optimal forest management [
21,
58,
59]. In recent years this technique has entered the field of forestry with studies by various researchers. Examples include resolving conflicts among economic, social, and environmental users of forests, the wood market, the impact of prices on wood income, and climate change as well as determining carbon boundaries.
For this reason, this study endeavors to analyze and resolve the conflict between environmental and economic stakeholders in the Hyrcanian forests of Iran in a logical manner, and to propose an innovative research idea by considering both environmental and economic approaches, as well as creating a balance between them.
The primary objectives of this research are to identify the optimal standing stock of the Hyrcanian forests by applying multi-objective decision-making methods and game theory, as well as to determine the Nash equilibrium and optimal Pareto solutions for forest management strategies. This study is the first to employ a multi-objective approach using an enhanced epsilon-constraint method (lexicographic) to determine the optimal forest stock.
2. Materials and Methods
The study was District 7 (Bargahe Zamin) in the Shafarood watershed, Guilan Province, Iran. These forests span altitudes ranging from 1,000 to 2,050 meters and cover an area of 1,064 hectares (
Figure 1). The region experiences an average annual rainfall of 899 mm, with an average temperature of 10.8°C. The forest is primarily dominated by Oriental beech (
Fagus orientalis) [
60].
2.1. Determination of the Volume per ha Relationship
Tree species in the area include beech, hornbeam, oak, alder, and other industrial species, which account for 55.93%, 25.47%, 12.21%, 1.04%, and 5.35% of the volume per ha, respectively, with a combined volume of 303.96 m³/ha [
60]. The volume per ha for these species is distributed as follows: beech 170 m³/ha, hornbeam 77.42 m³/ha, oak 3.16 m³/ha, alder 37.11 m³/ha, and other industrial species 16.26 m³/ha. Based on factors such as altitude, growth rates, regional potential, climatic conditions, and expert opinions, optimal inventory volumes and species percentages were determined through a questionnaire survey. Analysis of the survey results provided the optimal volume per ha and species distribution for the study area.
2.2. Growth Model
To estimate the harvest amount for each period, the relationship between volumetric growth and standing inventory is needed. This requires having the growth rate and standing volume for different species in various diameter classes [
61]. Using regression relationships between volume and growth, the growth equation for the region was obtained as follows:
G: Growth rate; V: Volume of tree species. a and b are estimated parameters from the regression analysis.
2.3. Carbon Sequestration Rate
The carbon content in the stand is assessed by determining the dry weight of above-ground biomass, which includes tree canopies and trunks. The weight of tree trunks across different diameter classes is computed using species-specific volume and density data, while canopy weight (in kilograms) is calculated using tree density per ha and allometric equations [
62]. For forest trees, it is assumed that 50% of the dry biomass weight represents stored carbon [
63].
The carbon model for various species in the standing stand is established based on the relationship between carbon stored per ha and the volume of standing biomass per ha.
CS: Carbon storage (t/ha); WD: Wood density (kg/m³); V: Volume per ha (m³/ha)
Finally, the Net Present Value (NPV) of carbon sequestration, or NPVc (10,000 Rials per ton per ha), was calculated using the following equation [
64]:
: Annual carbon storage; : Price per ton of carbon; : Interest rate
2.4. Stumpage Price
To calculate the average expected stumpage price of tree species, timber price at forest road side minus variable harvesting costs was used during the study period (1993-2019), and the consumer price index was used to adjust for inflation. Then, the following first order autoregressive model was used to predict the stumpage price [
65].
where,
is stumpage price at time
and
is stumpage price at time
.
We assumed that is a series of normally distributed errors with mean zero and autocorrelation zero.
Then, the equilibrium price for various species was calculated based on the following relation:
is the average expected net price. and are estimated parameters from the regression analysis.
2.5. Determining the Number of Labour
The required number of labour for forest harvesting was determined through a questionnaire. Coefficients representing the labour-to-volume ratio were derived uniformly across tree species, calculated by dividing the total labour count by the volume per ha of the respective trees.
2.6. Sensitivity Analysis
Variations in the interest rate have been examined, and the extent of changes in the objective functions in both models (multi-objective and game theory models) based on the optimal standing volume for different interest rates has been estimated. Then, the simulated values of the objective functions at different interest rates are compared with the present value.
2.7. Questionnaire Design
To establish model constraints such as optimal stock, percentage of tree species volume, annual harvest amount, and required labor per ha, a structured questionnaire was developed and implemented. This questionnaire included nine questions, each with four predefined options and an additional section for respondents to provide alternative answers based on their expertise. The survey was administered to faculty members of the Faculty of Natural Resources at the University of Guilan and forest experts from the Natural Resources Organization of Guilan Province.
Based on the accumulated responses, and averaging the preferred options, the outcomes were integrated into the relevant equations for analysis and implementation.
2.8. Multi-Objective Model
A classical multi-objective programming model can be outlined as follows:
where Z(x) is an objective function and
is a set of all p objective functions.
is the j th constrain function and
is the
th decision variable.
In multi-objective problems, instead of having a single objective function, multiple objective functions are simultaneously optimized. This results in the existence of more than one optimal solution, known as Pareto optimal responses. The primary aim of multi-objective optimization is to identify a set of Pareto optimal responses. Forest management objectives typically encompass social, economic, and environmental aspects. In this study, the economic objective involves maximizing the NPV of wood harvesting, while the environmental objective focuses on maximizing the amount of carbon sequestration. Therefore, the objective functions of the bi-objective programming model are as follows:
where
is an economic player's objective function and
is an environmental player's objective function.
After establishing the objective functions and defining the problem with appropriate constraints, the set of Pareto optimal responses was derived.
An effective approach for obtaining optimal Pareto solutions is through the utilization of the epsilon constraint method.
2.9. ε-epsilon Constraint Method
A procedure that overcomes some of the convexity problems of the weighted sum technique is the ℇ-constraint method. This involves minimizing a primary objective, , and expressing the other objectives in the form of inequality constraints.
In this method, we always focus on optimizing one of the objectives, while defining the highest acceptable bound for the other objectives within the constraints. For a two-objective problem, the following mathematical representation will be obtained:
By altering the values of the right-hand side of the new constraints
, the Pareto frontier of the problem will be obtained. One of the major drawbacks of the epsilon constraint method is the computational burden, as multiple values of
need to be tested for each of the transformed objective functions (
times). One common approach to implement the epsilon constraint method is to first compute the maximum and minimum of each individual objective function without considering the other objective functions, in the space
. Then, using the values obtained from the previous step, the relevant interval for each objective function is calculated. If we denote the maximum and minimum values of the objective functions respectively as
and
, then the interval for each of them is calculated using Equation (10):
The
interval is divided into
intervals. Then, for
in the Equation (10), it is possible to obtain
different values calculated through Equation (11).
In Equation (11),
represents the number of the new point related to
. Using the epsilon constraint method, the multi-objective optimization problem can be transformed into
single-objective optimization subproblems. Each subproblem has a solution space
, constrained by the inequalities associated with the objective functions
. Each subproblem leads to a candidate solution for the desired multi-objective optimization problem, or in other words, to the Pareto optimal front. Sometimes, some of the sub-problems create irrelevant solution spaces. Ultimately, after obtaining the Pareto optimal front, the decision-maker can select the most suitable solution according to their preferences [
66].
2.10. Lexicographic Optimization Method
In this approach, the various objectives are prioritized according to their importance to the decision-maker. For instance, objective
holds the highest importance, followed by
, and so forth. Lexicographic optimization assumes that the decision-maker values even a slight improvement in
over a significant improvement in
,
,
, and so on. Similarly, even a minor enhancement in
is preferred over a substantial increase in
,
, and so forth. Essentially, the decision-maker has lexicographic preferences, arranging potential solutions based on a lexicographic order of their objective function values. Lexicographic optimization is sometimes referred to as preemptive optimization since a slight improvement in one objective value preempts a much larger improvement in less significant objective values. In this research, decision-makers prioritize the current net value above all. They aim to maximize the current net value of wood harvesting while also seeking to maximize the amount of carbon sequestration. Therefore, they employ lexicographic optimization, where
represents the current net value and
represents the amount of carbon sequestration. A lexicographic maximization problem is typically expressed as follows:
The functions represent the objectives to be maximized, arranged in descending order of importance; x denotes the vector of decision variables, and X represents the feasible set, which encompasses the potential values of x. A lexicographic minimization problem can be similarly characterized.
2.11. Multi-Objective Game Theory Model (MOGM)
To apply a multi-objective game theory model to bi-objective problems concerning economic-environmental equilibrium, two distinct groups of environmental stakeholders were identified as players. The economic player (Player 1) comprises the users of Shafarood forests, such as operating companies, among others. On the other hand, the environmental player (Player 2) consists of advocates dedicated to preserving the environment and forests, including Natural Resources and Watershed Management Organization of Iran, Environmental Organization of Iran, and environmental NGOs.
To establish the negotiation framework within the game and also to determine the payoff in the game theory analysis, each player aims to ascertain their maximum (Dmax or Cmax) or minimum values (Dmin or Cmin) through the optimization of each individual objective analysis. Consequently, the range of maximum and minimum values (D, C) for each player was delineated as follows:
Once the range is established, signifying a pair of simulated values, namely
and
, derived from the initial MGOM outcomes, the first round of negotiations commences. Subsequently, each player defines their respective objective values of
or
as
and
, respectively. The ensuing equations indicate that each player's objective value will be treated as a constraint for the opposing party [
67].
The approach adopted by Player 1 is as follows:
The strategy of player 1 is:
The strategy of player 2 is:
If both players find the outcomes satisfactory, a Nash equilibrium will be achieved. Nash (1950, 1951) [
42,
68] introduced the pivotal concept of "Nash equilibrium," where no player has an incentive to change their strategy because no alternative strategy provides a better outcome given the choices of others. He demonstrated that in non-cooperative games, equilibrium solutions converge to the Nash bargaining solution as uncertainty diminishes over the bargaining set. The Nash bargaining solution maximizes the product of players' gains relative to their disagreement payoff [
69]. Nash (1950) [
68] established this solution as unique, adhering to principles such as scale invariance, symmetry, efficiency, and independence of irrelevant alternatives. Initially, in the first round of bargaining, players selected strategies aligned closely with their respective goals (Pmin and Dmax).
However, unsatisfied with the outcomes, the second round of negotiations commenced. Player 1 adjusted their economic income expectations downwards, while player 2 relaxed their environmental concerns. To ascertain each player's concession value, the max and min values of D and C were subdivided into small, equal segments. Concessions were incrementally raised with each round, with coefficient n determining the most appropriate concession value that would not significantly diminish the satisfaction of both players [
70]. Throughout the bargaining process, the disparity between the revised objective values and the MOGM results gradually diminished. This process continued until the final solutions of Dfinal and Cfinal were reached.
The Nash bargaining solution refers to the resolved value (Dfinal, Cfinal).
2.12. Sensitivity Analysis
Initially, the multi-objective model and game theory were employed to optimize forest inventory management among stakeholders with diverse objectives. Subsequently, a sensitivity analysis was conducted to assess the risk and accuracy of the model results. The original model computed the optimal solution using validated computations, followed by sensitivity analysis to evaluate the robustness of the outcomes.
In this study, a real interest rate of 6% was utilized, and sensitivity analysis involved varying interest rates to gauge their impact. Changes in the objective functions of both models were evaluated against an optimal standing volume of 457 m³ per ha based on the questionnaire across different interest rates. The simulated values of the objective functions at various interest rates were then compared to a reference present value to ascertain their sensitivity and reliability.
2.13. Objective Functions and Input Parameters
The input parameters for both models (multi-objective and game theory models) are presented in
Table 1). The index b represents the species type (beech, hornbeam, oak, alder, and other industrial species).
Table 2) shows the objective functions and input constraints of the model.
represents the harvest amount of species b.
4. Discussion
The Nash equilibrium identified in the game theory model of this study simplifies decision-making conditions for environmental and economic stakeholders, enabling informed choices based on available options. This approach becomes crucial when decision-making is complex due to the involvement of diverse stakeholders, allowing adaptation to environmental challenges while fostering economic growth within the constraints defined by the Nash equilibrium. This study's findings resonate with those of Moradi & Mohammadi Limaei (2018) [
73], underscoring the utility of Nash equilibrium in resolving decision-making dilemmas under competitive scenarios. In a similar study, Koltarza (2024) [
74] focuses on the use of Nash equilibrium as a tool for developing optimal harvesting strategies. The study demonstrates that employing Nash equilibrium can lead to the development of optimal harvesting strategies that consider both economic and environmental benefits. In another study, Siangulube (2024) [
75] emphasizes the necessity of private sector participation and the importance of prioritizing local needs and the demands of marginalized people while downplaying the usefulness of formal laws and regulations as the ultimate means to resolve landscape issues. In similar contexts, Ratner et al. (2022) [
76] emphasized that in the absence of trust and other democratic elements, negotiating trade-offs is difficult, and the governance paradigm mostly shifts to relying on dominant formal systems of rules and regulations, which may escalate conflicts.
Comparison between Nash equilibrium values and Pareto optimal values reveals distinct methodologies in game theory and multi-objective optimization. This disparity has been previously discussed by Moradi & Mohammadi Limaei (2018) [
73], Madani (2010) [
77], and Lee (2012) [
57]. The multi-objective optimization model offers a spectrum of Pareto optimal points, each representing a feasible compromise between environmental and economic considerations that decision-makers can select based on stakeholder preferences. In contrast, the game theory model, after iterative negotiation rounds, converges on a Nash equilibrium where players pursue self-interest, presenting decision-makers with a limited yet balanced range of choices encompassing economic and environmental objectives. Eyvindson et al. (2023) [
58] emphasizes stakeholder engagement through interactive tools that allow users to examine the impact of different scenarios in forest planning, aiding in better and more balanced decision-making. Their study uses multi-objective optimization techniques to determine Pareto optimal points in forest planning, helping decision-makers find a balance between various objectives.
In this study, direct interaction with stakeholders across different scenarios was not explored. Instead, the focus was on decision-making outcomes using game theory models and multi-objective optimization, specifically aiming for Nash equilibrium and Pareto optimal points in managing the Hyrcanian forests. While the multi-objective model and the Pareto frontier contribute to balancing economic and environmental objectives, Nash equilibrium plays a more prominent role in improving the decision-making process for optimal forest resource management.
Our findings align with Moradi & Mohammadi Limaei's (2018) study [
73], which highlights the game theory model's advantage in decision-making by simplifying the selection process. In contrast, the multi-objective epsilon constraint method used here, though effective in ranking and narrowing the Pareto optimal range, provides a broader decision-making scope. Consequently, the game theory model is more efficient for decision-makers seeking to balance environmental protection (EnvP) with economic development (EcoD) goals [
73].
Çalışkan and Özden (2022) [
78] also emphasize the potential of game theory to enhance sustainability policies in international forestry. They underscore how game theory can illustrate the necessity of strategic cooperation among countries and stakeholders for more effective forest resource management. Their findings indicate that game theory can refine decision-making processes in international forestry policies. Specifically, bargaining games can aid in resource allocation, zero-sum games can assess competitive dynamics between countries, and the prisoner’s dilemma can underscore the importance of strategic cooperation. Our study similarly addresses sustainability in the management of the Hyrcanian forests, aiming to balance economic and environmental objectives through game theory techniques. Both studies explore the impact of varying parameters—such as interest rates in our study and game conditions in Çalışkan and Özden's (2022) [
78] study—on outcomes. The parallels between these studies highlight the efficacy of game theory in forest resource management and in enhancing decision-making processes. Both demonstrate that game theory can help achieve a better balance between economic and environmental objectives while fostering stronger cooperation among stakeholders. These shared insights offer a valuable foundation for advancing policies and management strategies in forestry and natural resource management.
Nabhani et al. (2024) [
3] investigated the optimization of economic and environmental objectives in ecosystem services under conditions of uncertainty. Their study provides a comprehensive analysis of Pareto optimal points in ecosystem service optimization, demonstrating how these points can represent the balance between various objectives. However, their focus is predominantly on the application of game theory models and multi-objective optimization under deterministic conditions. While the study explores both Pareto optimal points and the distinction between Nash equilibrium and Pareto optimal points, it places greater emphasis on Nash equilibrium. A sensitivity analysis was conducted for both the multi-objective and game theory models at the optimal standing volume level of 457 m³/ha, considering interest rates ranging from 4% to 20%. The results consistently indicate that as interest rates increase, the Net Present Value (NPV) decreases while the harvest volume rises. This trend suggests that higher interest rates incentivize earlier harvesting, as the expected NPV declines with increasing interest rates. These findings are consistent with those of Mohammadi Limaei and Mohammadi (2023) [
79].
Çalışkan, H., & Özden, S. (2022) [
78] used sensitivity analysis to explore the effects of various game scenarios on decision-making, illustrating how alterations in game conditions can lead to different outcomes. In our study, the sensitivity analysis of interest rates reveals their impact on harvest volume and net present value, demonstrating how fluctuations in interest rates can influence managerial decision-making. This study demonstrates the feasibility of achieving simultaneous economic and environmental objectives through both multi-objective and game theory models in optimizing Hyrcanian forest management. Nabhani et al. (2024) [
3] underscore the importance of considering multiple objectives in forest management and policy under uncertain wood prices, preventing undesired effects from a singular or deterministic approach. This work provides insights into trade-offs and synergies, contributing to strategic planning and policy design. Owing to the current logging moratorium on Iran’s Hyrcanian forests, proactive planning is essential for the post-moratorium period. Determining optimal growth and harvest volumes that balance economic benefits with environmental sustainability will be crucial.
5. Conclusions
The modeling framework utilized in this research provides insights into planning sustainable forest harvesting levels o, aiming to maximize forest growth potential while maintaining optimal standing volumes. Furthermore, the model's flexibility allows for the integration of diverse uses such as social benefits and ecotourism, which can be prioritized based on evolving societal needs.
To enhance the resilience and sustainability of forest management practices in the region, integrating climate change considerations into game theory modeling is recommended to prepare for future environmental challenges. Additionally, addressing social concerns alongside economic and environmental goals.
These strategies aim to refine forest management approaches, ensuring alignment with economic, environmental, and social objectives amidst evolving conditions. By adopting these measures, stakeholders can effectively navigate the complexities of forest management and foster sustainable development in the Hyrcanian forests and beyond.
Figure 1.
Study Area: a) Guilan Province, b) Shafarood Watershed, c) District (7) Bagahe Zamin.
Figure 1.
Study Area: a) Guilan Province, b) Shafarood Watershed, c) District (7) Bagahe Zamin.
Figure 2.
Pareto Optimal frontier at forest stock level (1).
Figure 2.
Pareto Optimal frontier at forest stock level (1).
Figure 3.
Pareto Optimal frontier at forest stock level (2).
Figure 3.
Pareto Optimal frontier at forest stock level (2).
Figure 4.
Pareto Optimal frontier at forest stock level (3).
Figure 4.
Pareto Optimal frontier at forest stock level (3).
Figure 5.
Pareto Optimal frontier at forest stock level (4).
Figure 5.
Pareto Optimal frontier at forest stock level (4).
Figure 6.
Pareto Optimal frontier at forest stock level (5).
Figure 6.
Pareto Optimal frontier at forest stock level (5).
Figure 7.
Range of objective function variations for each player at the stock level of (1).
Figure 7.
Range of objective function variations for each player at the stock level of (1).
Figure 8.
Range of objective function variations for each player at the stock level of (2).
Figure 8.
Range of objective function variations for each player at the stock level of (2).
Figure 9.
Range of objective function variations for each player at the stock level of (3).
Figure 9.
Range of objective function variations for each player at the stock level of (3).
Figure 10.
Range of objective function variations for each player at the stock level of (4).
Figure 10.
Range of objective function variations for each player at the stock level of (4).
Figure 11.
Range of objective function variations for each player at the stock level of (5).
Figure 11.
Range of objective function variations for each player at the stock level of (5).
Figure 13.
Sensitivity of NPV to Interest Rate Changes for Optimal Standing Inventory of 457 (m³/ha).
Figure 13.
Sensitivity of NPV to Interest Rate Changes for Optimal Standing Inventory of 457 (m³/ha).
Table 1.
Input Parameters of the Bi-Objective Game Theory Model.
Table 1.
Input Parameters of the Bi-Objective Game Theory Model.
Parameters |
Explanations |
|
The NPV of timber harvesting of species b |
|
Amount of harvesting coefficient for species b |
|
Growth rate of species b |
|
Number of species b per ha |
|
Volume of species b per ha |
|
Maximum number of labour |
|
coefficient used for each labour |
|
Income of each labour |
|
Income coefficient from each labour for harvesting species b |
|
Allowed growth capacity for species b |
|
Growth coefficient for species b |
|
Optimal inventory for species b |
|
Value ofharvestable volume for species b |
|
Coefficient of harvestable volume for Species b |
|
Total NPV |
|
NPV Coefficient |
|
Amount of carbon sequestration |
|
Carbon sequestration coefficient |
Table 2.
Objective functions and input constraints for both models.
Table 2.
Objective functions and input constraints for both models.
(1) |
|
|
(2) |
|
|
(3) |
|
|
(4) |
|
|
(5) |
|
|
(6) |
|
|
(7) |
|
|
(8) |
|
|
(9) |
|
|
(10) |
|
|
(11) |
|
|
(12) |
|
|
(13) |
|
|
(14) |
|
|
Table 3.
Volume and type of studied species.
Table 3.
Volume and type of studied species.
Species Name |
Variable |
Acceptable volume (%) |
Acceptable Volume(m3/ha) |
Beech |
X1
|
55 |
251.4 |
Hornbeam |
X2
|
13 |
59.4 |
Oak |
X3
|
16 |
73.1 |
Alder |
X4
|
9 |
41.1 |
Other industrial species |
X5
|
7 |
32 |
Total |
X |
100 |
457 |
Table 5.
Logarithmic Functions and Coefficients for Each Species.
Table 5.
Logarithmic Functions and Coefficients for Each Species.
Species Name |
Variable |
Logarithmic Functions |
Predicted volume (m³/ha) |
Predicted growth (m³/ha) |
Coefficients |
Beech |
X1
|
|
251.4 |
1.34 |
0.0053 |
Hornbeam |
X2
|
|
59.4 |
0.44 |
0.0074 |
Oak |
X3
|
|
73.1 |
0.4 |
0.0055 |
Alder |
X4
|
|
41.1 |
0.68 |
0.0165 |
Other industrial species |
X5
|
|
32 |
0.51 |
0.0159 |
Total |
X |
|
457 |
3.37 |
- |
Table 6.
NPV of harvestable volume.
Table 6.
NPV of harvestable volume.
Species Name |
Variable |
Mean expected stumpage price (10000 Rials/ m3) |
Harvestable volume (m3/ha) |
NPV of harvestable volume (10000 Rials) |
Beech |
X1
|
667.22 |
0.67 |
7175.56 |
Hornbeam |
X2
|
377.59 |
0.22 |
1333.38 |
Oak |
X3
|
405.46 |
0.2 |
1301.62 |
Alder |
X4
|
571.86 |
0.34 |
3120.91 |
Other industrial species |
X5
|
540.08 |
0.255 |
2210.58 |
Total |
X |
- |
1.685 |
15142.05 |
Table 7.
Optimal stock values for each species at different levels.
Table 7.
Optimal stock values for each species at different levels.
Objective functions |
Solution |
() Beech (m3/ha) |
Hornbeam () (m3/ha) |
() Alder (m3/ha) |
() Oak (m3/ha) |
() Other (m3/ha) |
(m3/ha) |
|
170 |
77.42 |
3.16 |
37.11 |
16.26 |
303.96 |
190.35 |
72.92 |
20.65 |
38.11 |
20.2 |
342.21 |
|
210.7 |
68.41 |
38.13 |
39.11 |
24.13 |
380.475 |
231.05 |
63.91 |
55.62 |
40.1 |
28.07 |
418.74 |
251.4 |
59.4 |
73.1 |
41.1 |
32 |
475 |
Table 8.
Optimal values of the Pareto for objective functions at stock level one.
Table 8.
Optimal values of the Pareto for objective functions at stock level one.
Grid |
Solutions |
NPV of forest harvesting (Z1) (10000 Rials/ha) |
NPV of carbon sequestration (Z2) (ton/ha) |
Growth (G) (m3/ha) |
Amount of harvest (m3/ha) |
Grid 1 (303.96 m3/ha)
|
Solution 1 |
10993.4 |
106.17 |
1.185 |
1.128 |
Solution 2 |
10648.08 |
106.19 |
1.24 |
1.073 |
Solution 3 |
10302.76 |
106.21 |
1.295 |
1.018 |
Solution 4 |
9957.43 |
106.23 |
1.35 |
0.963 |
Solution 5 |
9612.11 |
106.25 |
1.4 |
0.913 |
Solution 6 |
9266.79 |
106.27 |
1.459 |
0.854 |
Solution 7 |
8779.62 |
106.29 |
1.519 |
0.794 |
Solution 8 |
8223.06 |
106.31 |
1.581 |
0.732 |
Solution 9 |
7626.5 |
106.32 |
1.645 |
0.668 |
Solution 10 |
6995.12 |
106.34 |
1.712 |
0.601 |
Solution 11 |
6363.75 |
106.36 |
1.778 |
0.535 |
Solution 12 |
5732.37 |
106.38 |
1.844 |
0.469 |
Solution 13 |
5101 |
106.4 |
1.91 |
0.403 |
Solution 14 |
4463.93 |
106.42 |
1.969 |
0.344 |
Solution 15 |
3826.22 |
106.44 |
2.026 |
0.287 |
Solution 16 |
3188.52 |
106.46 |
2.083 |
0.23 |
Solution 17 |
2550.82 |
106.48 |
2.141 |
0.172 |
Solution 18 |
1913.11 |
106.5 |
2.198 |
0.115 |
Solution 19 |
1275.41 |
106.52 |
2.255 |
0.058 |
Solution 20 |
637.7 |
106.54 |
2.313 |
0 |
Table 9.
Pareto Optimal Values for Objective Functions at Level Two.
Table 9.
Pareto Optimal Values for Objective Functions at Level Two.
Grid |
Solutions |
NPV of forest harvesting (Z1) (10000 Rials/ha) |
NPV of carbon sequestration (Z2) (ton/ha) |
Growth (G) (m3/ha) |
Amount of harvest (m3/ha) |
Grid 2 (342.21 m3/ha)
|
Solution 1 |
12175.67 |
119.55 |
1.31 |
1.25 |
Solution 2 |
11794.61 |
119.57 |
1.37 |
1.19 |
Solution 3 |
11413.54 |
119.59 |
1.43 |
1.13 |
Solution 4 |
11032.47 |
119.61 |
1.49 |
1.07 |
Solution 5 |
10651.41 |
119.63 |
1.55 |
1.01 |
Solution 6 |
10234.36 |
119.65 |
1.62 |
0.94 |
Solution 7 |
9672.23 |
119.67 |
1.68 |
0.88 |
Solution 8 |
9058.06 |
119.69 |
1.75 |
0.81 |
Solution 9 |
8416.74 |
119.71 |
1.82 |
0.74 |
Solution 10 |
7720.01 |
119.74 |
1.89 |
0.67 |
Solution 11 |
7023.28 |
119.76 |
1.97 |
0.59 |
Solution 12 |
6326.55 |
119.78 |
2.04 |
0.52 |
Solution 13 |
5629.71 |
119.8 |
2.11 |
0.45 |
Solution 14 |
4926 |
119.82 |
2.18 |
0.38 |
Solution 15 |
4222.28 |
119.84 |
2.24 |
0.32 |
Solution 16 |
3518.57 |
119.86 |
2.3 |
0.26 |
Solution 17 |
2814.86 |
119.88 |
2.37 |
0.19 |
Solution 18 |
2111.14 |
119.91 |
2.43 |
0.13 |
Solution 19 |
1407.43 |
119.93 |
2.49 |
0.07 |
Solution 20 |
703.14 |
119.95 |
2.56 |
0 |
Table 10.
Pareto Optimal Values for Objective Functions at Level Three.
Table 10.
Pareto Optimal Values for Objective Functions at Level Three.
Grid |
Solutions |
NPV of forest harvesting (Z1) (10000 Rials/ha) |
NPV of carbon sequestration (Z2) (ton/ha) |
Growth (G) (m3/ha) |
Amount of harvest (m3/ha) |
Grid 3 (380.475 m3/ha)
|
Solution 1 |
13357.95 |
132.92 |
1.44 |
1.36 |
Solution 2 |
12941.14 |
132.94 |
1.5 |
1.3 |
Solution 3 |
12524.32 |
132.97 |
1.57 |
1.23 |
Solution 4 |
12107.51 |
132.99 |
1.63 |
1.17 |
Solution 5 |
11677.99 |
133.01 |
1.7 |
1.1 |
Solution 6 |
11188.32 |
133.03 |
1.77 |
1.03 |
Solution 7 |
10564.83 |
133.06 |
1.85 |
0.95 |
Solution 8 |
9893.06 |
133.08 |
1.92 |
0.88 |
Solution 9 |
9206.98 |
133.1 |
2 |
0.8 |
Solution 10 |
8444.9 |
133.13 |
2.08 |
0.72 |
Solution 11 |
7682.82 |
133.15 |
2.16 |
0.64 |
Solution 12 |
6920.73 |
133.17 |
2.24 |
0.56 |
Solution 13 |
6157.79 |
13.2 |
2.32 |
0.48 |
Solution 14 |
5388.07 |
133.22 |
2.39 |
0.41 |
Solution 15 |
4618.34 |
133.24 |
2.45 |
0.35 |
Solution 16 |
3848.62 |
133.27 |
2.52 |
0.28 |
Solution 17 |
3078.9 |
133.29 |
2.59 |
0.21 |
Solution 18 |
2309.17 |
133.31 |
2.66 |
0.14 |
Solution 19 |
1539.45 |
133.34 |
2.73 |
0.07 |
Solution 20 |
769.72 |
133.36 |
2.8 |
0 |
Table 11.
Pareto Optimal Values for Objective Functions at Level Four.
Table 11.
Pareto Optimal Values for Objective Functions at Level Four.
Grid |
Solutions |
NPV of forest harvesting (Z1) (10000 Rials/ha) |
NPV of carbon sequestration (Z2) (ton/ha) |
Growth (G) (m3/ha) |
Amount of harvest (m3/ha) |
Grid 4 (418.74 m3/ha)
|
Solution 1 |
14540.22 |
146.29 |
1.56 |
1.48 |
Solution 2 |
14087.67 |
146.32 |
1.63 |
1.41 |
Solution 3 |
13635.11 |
146.34 |
1.7 |
1.34 |
Solution 4 |
13182.55 |
146.37 |
1.78 |
1.27 |
Solution 5 |
12673.94 |
146.39 |
1.85 |
1.19 |
Solution 6 |
12142.27 |
146.42 |
1.93 |
1.11 |
Solution 7 |
11457.44 |
146.44 |
2.01 |
1.03 |
Solution 8 |
10728.05 |
146.47 |
2.09 |
0.95 |
Solution 9 |
9997.23 |
146.49 |
2.17 |
0.87 |
Solution 10 |
9169.79 |
146.52 |
2.26 |
0.78 |
Solution 11 |
8342.35 |
146.54 |
2.35 |
0.7 |
Solution 12 |
7514.91 |
146.57 |
2.43 |
0.61 |
Solution 13 |
6685.87 |
146.59 |
2.52 |
0.53 |
Solution 14 |
5850.14 |
146.62 |
2.59 |
0.45 |
Solution 15 |
5014.4 |
146.65 |
2.67 |
0.38 |
Solution 16 |
4178.67 |
146.67 |
2.74 |
0.3 |
Solution 17 |
3342.94 |
146.7 |
2.82 |
0.23 |
Solution 18 |
2507.2 |
146.72 |
2.89 |
0.15 |
Solution 19 |
1671.47 |
146.75 |
2.97 |
0.08 |
Solution 20 |
835.73 |
146.77 |
3.04 |
0 |
Table 12.
Pareto Optimal Values for Objective Functions at Level Five.
Table 12.
Pareto Optimal Values for Objective Functions at Level Five.
Grid |
Solutions |
NPV of forest harvesting (Z1) (10000 Rials/ha) |
NPV of carbon sequestration (Z2) (ton/ha) |
Growth (G) (m3/ha) |
Amount of harvest (m3/ha) |
Grid 4 (475 m3/ha)
|
Solution 1 |
15722.5 |
159.67 |
1.69 |
1.6 |
Solution 2 |
15234.19 |
159.69 |
1.76 |
1.53 |
Solution 3 |
14745.89 |
159.72 |
1.84 |
1.45 |
Solution 4 |
14243.54 |
159.75 |
1.92 |
1.37 |
Solution 5 |
13669.88 |
159.78 |
2 |
1.29 |
Solution 6 |
13096.23 |
159.8 |
2.09 |
1.2 |
Solution 7 |
12350.05 |
159.83 |
2.18 |
1.11 |
Solution 8 |
11536.05 |
159.86 |
2.26 |
1.03 |
Solution 9 |
10776.06 |
159.88 |
2.35 |
0.94 |
Solution 10 |
9894.68 |
159.9 |
2.44 |
0.85 |
Solution 11 |
9001.88 |
159.94 |
2.54 |
0.75 |
Solution 12 |
8109.09 |
159.97 |
2.63 |
0.66 |
Solution 13 |
7213.95 |
159.99 |
2.72 |
0.57 |
Solution 14 |
6312.21 |
159.02 |
2.8 |
0.49 |
Solution 15 |
5410.46 |
160.05 |
2.88 |
0.41 |
Solution 16 |
4508.72 |
160.07 |
2.96 |
0.32 |
Solution 17 |
3606.98 |
160.1 |
3.05 |
0.24 |
Solution 18 |
2705.23 |
160.13 |
3.13 |
0.16 |
Solution 19 |
1803.49 |
160.16 |
3.21 |
0.08 |
Solution 20 |
901.74 |
160.18 |
3.29 |
0 |
Table 13.
Objective Function Results for Each Player at Level One Standing Stock.
Table 13.
Objective Function Results for Each Player at Level One Standing Stock.
Grid |
Game round |
Players |
NPV of forest harvesting (Z1) (10000 Rials/ha) |
NPV of carbon sequestration (Z2) (ton/ha) |
Gride1 (303.96 m3/ha)
|
1-1 |
Player 1 |
1275.408 |
106.517 |
1-2 |
Player 2 |
9894.058 |
106.2324 |
2-1 |
Player 1 |
2550.815 |
106.4786 |
2-2 |
Player 2 |
8794.718 |
106.286 |
3-1 |
Player 1 |
3826.223 |
106.4402 |
3-1 |
Player 2 |
7695.378 |
106.3228 |
4-1 |
Player 1 |
5101.001 |
106.4017 |
4-2 |
Player 2 |
6596.038 |
106.3562 |
5-1 |
Player 1 |
6363.748 |
106.3633 |
5-2 |
Player 2 |
5496.699 |
106.3897 |
Table 14.
Objective Function Results for Each Player at Level Two Standing Stock.
Table 14.
Objective Function Results for Each Player at Level Two Standing Stock.
Grid |
Game round |
Players |
NPV of forest harvesting (Z1) (10000 Rials/ha) |
NPV of carbon sequestration (Z2) (ton/ha) |
Gride 2 (342.21 m3/ha)
|
1-1 |
Player 1 |
1407.427 |
119.9267 |
1-2 |
Player 2 |
10958.1 |
119.6128 |
2-1 |
Player 1 |
2814.855 |
119.8843 |
2-2 |
Player 2 |
9740.538 |
119.6699 |
3-1 |
Player 1 |
4222.282 |
119.8419 |
3-2 |
Player 2 |
8522.97 |
119.7114 |
4-1 |
Player 1 |
5629.71 |
119.7995 |
4-2 |
Player 2 |
7305.403 |
119.7485 |
5-1 |
Player 1 |
7023.282 |
119.7571 |
5-2 |
Player 2 |
6087.836 |
119.7855 |
Table 15.
Objective function results for each player at level the stock level of (3).
Table 15.
Objective function results for each player at level the stock level of (3).
Grid |
Game round |
Players |
NPV of forest harvesting (Z1) (10000 Rials/ha) |
NPV of carbon sequestration (Z2) (ton/ha) |
Gride3 (380.48 m3/ha)
|
1-1 |
Player 1 |
1539.447 |
133.3363 |
1-2 |
Player 2 |
12022.15 |
132.9933 |
2-1 |
Player 1 |
3078.895 |
133.29 |
2-2 |
Player 2 |
10686.36 |
133.0539 |
3-1 |
Player 1 |
4618.342 |
133.2436 |
3-2 |
Player 2 |
9350.562 |
133.1 |
4-1 |
Player 1 |
6157.79 |
133.1972 |
4-2 |
Player 2 |
8014.768 |
133.1407 |
5-1 |
Player 1 |
7682.816 |
133.1508 |
5-2 |
Player 2 |
6678.973 |
133.1814 |
Table 16.
Objective function results for each player at the fourth level of stock.
Table 16.
Objective function results for each player at the fourth level of stock.
Grid |
Game round |
Players |
NPV of forest harvesting (Z1) (10000 Rials/ha) |
NPV of carbon sequestration (Z2) (ton/ha) |
Gride4 (418.74 m3/ha)
|
1-1 |
Player 1 |
1671.476 |
146.746 |
1-2 |
Player 2 |
13086.2 |
146.3737 |
2-1 |
Player 1 |
3342.935 |
146.6975 |
2-2 |
Player 2 |
11632.18 |
146.4379 |
3-1 |
Player 1 |
5014.402 |
146.6453 |
3-2 |
Player 2 |
10178.15 |
146.488 |
4-1 |
Player 1 |
6685.87 |
146.5949 |
4-2 |
Player 2 |
8724.133 |
146.533 |
5-1 |
Player 1 |
8342.35 |
146.5446 |
5-2 |
Player 2 |
7270.11 |
146.5772 |
Table 17.
Objective Function Results for Each Player at the fifth level of stock.
Table 17.
Objective Function Results for Each Player at the fifth level of stock.
Grid |
Game round |
Players |
NPV of forest harvesting (Z1) (10000 Rials/ha) |
NPV of carbon sequestration (Z2) (ton/ha) |
Gride5 (457 m3/ha)
|
1-1 |
Player 1 |
1803.487 |
160.1557 |
1-2 |
Player 2 |
14150.25 |
159.7526 |
2-1 |
Player 1 |
3606.975 |
160.1013 |
2-2 |
Player 2 |
12578 |
159.8218 |
3-1 |
Player 1 |
5410.462 |
160.047 |
3-2 |
Player 2 |
11005.75 |
159.8761 |
4-1 |
Player 1 |
7213.949 |
159.9927 |
4-2 |
Player 2 |
9433.497 |
159.9252 |
5-1 |
Player 1 |
9001.884 |
159.9383 |
5-2 |
Player 2 |
7861.248 |
159.9731 |
Table 18.
Objective function values, total growth, harvest amount, and stock by species at different levels of stock.
Table 18.
Objective function values, total growth, harvest amount, and stock by species at different levels of stock.
Stock (m3/ha) |
Game Round |
Objective |
Solution |
NPV of carbon sequestration (Z2) (ton/ha) |
NPV of harvesting (Z2) (10000 Rials/ha) |
Growth |
Harvest |
X1 (Beech) |
X2 (Hornbea) |
X3 (Alder) |
X4 (Oak) |
X5 (Other) |
303.96 |
5-1 |
106.36 |
6363.75 |
1.78 |
0.59 |
170 |
77.42 |
3.16 |
37.11 |
16.26 |
303.96 |
5-2 |
106.39 |
5496.7 |
1.87 |
0.5 |
|
|
|
|
|
342.21 |
5-1 |
119.76 |
7023.28 |
1.97 |
0.65 |
190.35 |
72.92 |
20.65 |
38.11 |
20.2 |
342.21 |
5-2 |
119.82 |
6087.84 |
2.06 |
0.56 |
|
|
|
|
|
380.48 |
5-1 |
133.15 |
7682.82 |
2.16 |
0.71 |
210.7 |
68.41 |
38.13 |
39.11 |
24.13 |
380.48 |
5-2 |
133.18 |
6678.97 |
2.26 |
0.61 |
|
|
|
|
|
418.74 |
5-1 |
146.54 |
8342.35 |
2.35 |
0.77 |
231.05 |
63.91 |
55.62 |
40.1 |
28.07 |
418.74 |
5-2 |
146.58 |
7270.11 |
2.46 |
0.66 |
|
|
|
|
|
457 |
5-1 |
159.94 |
9001.88 |
2.54 |
0.83 |
251.4 |
59.4 |
73.1 |
41.1 |
32 |
457 |
5-2 |
159.97 |
7861.25 |
2.66 |
0.71 |
|
|
|
|
|
Table 19.
Optimal growth and harvest volumes for each Species at various levels of stock for each player.
Table 19.
Optimal growth and harvest volumes for each Species at various levels of stock for each player.
Stock (m³/ha) |
Harvest/Growth (m³/ha) |
Players |
Beech |
Hornbeam |
Alder |
Oak |
Other |
303.96 |
Growth |
Player 1 |
0.45 |
0.57 |
0.017 |
0.47 |
0.3 |
Player 2 |
0.45 |
0.57 |
0.017 |
0.57 |
0.3 |
Harvest |
Player 1 |
0.453 |
- |
- |
0.139 |
- |
Player 2 |
0.453 |
- |
- |
0.048 |
- |
342.21 |
Growth |
Player 1 |
0.51 |
0.54 |
0.113 |
0.49 |
0.322 |
Player 2 |
0.51 |
0.54 |
0.113 |
0.58 |
0.322 |
Harvest |
Player 1 |
0.507 |
- |
- |
0.145 |
- |
Player 2 |
0.507 |
- |
- |
0.047 |
- |
380.48 |
Growth |
Player 1 |
0.56 |
0.51 |
0.21 |
0.5 |
0.38 |
Player 2 |
0.56 |
0.51 |
0.21 |
0.6 |
0.38 |
Harvest |
Player 1 |
0.562 |
- |
- |
0.151 |
- |
Player 2 |
0.562 |
- |
- |
0.046 |
- |
418.74 |
Growth |
Player 1 |
0.62 |
0.47 |
0.3 |
0.51 |
0.45 |
Player 2 |
0.62 |
0.47 |
0.3 |
0.62 |
0.45 |
Harvest |
Player 1 |
0.616 |
- |
- |
0.157 |
- |
Player 2 |
0.616 |
- |
- |
0.044 |
- |
457 |
Growth |
Player 1 |
0.67 |
0.44 |
0.4 |
0.52 |
0.51 |
Player 2 |
0.67 |
0.44 |
0.4 |
0.64 |
0.51 |
Harvest |
Player 1 |
0.67 |
- |
- |
0.163 |
- |
Player 2 |
0.67 |
- |
- |
0.043 |
- |