Preprint
Article

Using Carbon tax to reach the US’s 2050 NDCs goals - A CGE Model of Firms, Government and Households

Altmetrics

Downloads

126

Views

59

Comments

0

A peer-reviewed article of this preprint also exists.

This version is not peer-reviewed

Submitted:

23 May 2023

Posted:

25 May 2023

You are already at the latest version

Alerts
Abstract
Our study shows how the United States government can achieve its goal of Nationally Determined Contribution (NDC) in 2025, 2030, and 2050 by reducing energy consumption through a pure carbon tax. To achieve its emissions reduction goals, it is necessary for the US to impose a long-term carbon tax that balances taxes on labour, capital, energy, and carbon. Therefore, in this study, through the two-layer CGE Cobb-Douglas model, the carbon tax rate is set while balancing the production and profit functions of government, businesses, and households. This study concludes that the carbon price will increase from US$ 0.4391/kg CO2 in 2020 to US$ 2.5671/kg CO2 in 2050 when the CO2 emissions reduction target is increased from 17% reduction in 2020 to 83% reduction in 2050 for the US.
Keywords: 
Subject: Business, Economics and Management  -   Finance

Introduction

Carbon taxes are often thought to force companies to use energy more efficiently and use cleaner energy to reduce carbon emissions, but the economic environment is changing from year to year, and it is an almost impossible task to use a fixed carbon tax to achieve a win-win situation for both companies and governments in a changing environment. Refusal of the Kyoto Protocol in 2011 and withdrawal from the Paris Agreement in 2017, indicates there is great uncertainty about environmental policy in the US. Which provides more freedom to industry to consume fossil fuels. But the effect of global warming will be universal and to reduce emissions the US needs to be an integral part of the process. Our study provides a framework for the US government to achieve its goal of NDC in 2025, 2030, and 2050 by issuing a dynamic carbon tax. While carbon taxes are effective in reducing emissions, a comprehensive approach to balance carbon taxes with taxes and expenditure in other sectors of the economy, such as firms and households, has not been adopted.
Many studies (Baranzini et al., 2000; Davis and Kilian, 2009; Marron et al., 2015) have confirmed the role of carbon taxes in reducing carbon emissions, but an inappropriate carbon tax could also reduce economic growth and increase spending by businesses and households as it directly impacts prices of labour, capital, and energy. Therefore, it is important to analyse the balance between different social units and environmental policies before setting a carbon tax rate. With proper design, a carbon tax can be a powerful mitigation tool that can help achieve socio-economic goals.
Energy is essential in enabling systems that satisfy the need for sustenance, employment, shelter, and transportation. In the US, by 2010 consumers were spending more than half a trillion dollars each year on energy for agriculture, electricity, heating, manufacturing industries, construction, transport, residential building, and commercial services (Krupnick et al., 2010). Spending on energy increased to US$1.1 trillion in 2017, which represents 5.8% of the gross domestic product (GDP) (US Energy Information Administration, 2021). Energy from fossil fuels is truly the lifeblood of the country.
Figure 1 shows the primary energy consumption1 by source measured in terawatt-hours (TWh) for the US from 1965 to 2018. In 2018, 93.4% of energy consumption in the US was produced from fossil fuels, including oil (44.3%), natural gas (33.8%) and coal (15.3%). Indeed, renewable sources of consumption were only 6.6% of full primary energy consumption.
Figure 2 shows the renewable energy investment rate (as % of GDP) for nine economies in the G20 in 2015. The US invested the least relative to contributors to renewable energy. Thus, the US will remain dependent on fossil fuels for the future because of no major policy initiatives to reduce carbon emissions.
Carbon emissions are the major cause of many diseases, increases in temperatures and rise in sea levels, global climate change, acid rain, hazardous air pollution, smog, radioactive waste, and habitat destruction (Natural Resources Defence Council, 2018). However, with insufficient investment in clean energy and stricter environmental policies and regulations, the US emitted the world’s second largest amount of CO2 emissions in 2017, 5.27 billion tonnes, and has emitted around 400 billion tonnes of CO2 emissions into the atmosphere since 1750, making the US responsible for 25% of the world’s historical emissions (Global Carbon Project, 2019).
In response to the Copenhagen Accord (2010), the US submitted a mitigation action plan to the executive secretary of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) in 2010. This action plan set up an economy-wide target for reduction of greenhouse gas emissions. Accordingly, when compared to the emissions levels of the base year 2005, the US intended to reach a short-term target of reducing its CO2 emissions by 17% by 2020; a mid-term target of reducing its CO2 emissions by 30% in 2025 and 42% in 2030; a long-term target of reducing its CO2 emissions by 83% in 2050. Five years later, in 2015, the US submitted the NDCtarget in response to the Paris Agreement’s long-term temperature goal of limiting warming to well below 2°C. The current NDC target for the US is to reduce emissions by 26%-28% below its 2005 level by 2025, and 80% below its 2005 level by 2050 (United Nations, 2016).
However, after failing to ratify the Tokyo Protocol in 2011, the United States announced in 2017 that it was withdrawing from the Paris Agreement (IPCC, 2019)2. The US government released the Affordable Clean Energy (ACE) rule on June 19, 2019, replacing the previous administration’s Clean Power Plan, with rules that restore the rule of law, empower states, and support energy diversity in order to meet the nation’s NDC goals. However, compared to the Clean Power Plan’s roughly 32% reduction in power sector emissions, ACE is expected to reduce power sector emissions by only 1% (IPCC, 2019; Natural Resources Defence Council, 2018). In 2018, the US government also froze mileage per gallon standards for cars and light trucks produced after 2020. Larsen et al. (2019) note that freezing vehicle emissions and fuel economy standards for cars and light trucks will increase transportation sector CO2 emissions by 28-83 Mt CO2 per year by 2030. Although 25 gubernatorial representatives have joined the US Climate Alliance 3 and California has encouraged some automakers to strengthen vehicle fuel consumption and emissions standards, existing US efforts to meet the NDC targets in 2025, 2030, and 2050 will be difficult (IPCC, 2019).
Despite these issues, our study presents simulation results on how the US administration can achieve the NDC target by issuing a dynamic carbon tax. Our study recommends that a long run carbon tax in the US is needed, and it can yield at least the first and second dividends, but only if it is done correctly, keeping in equilibrium the tax costs of labour, capital, energy and carbon. First and second dividends refer to achieving higher tax collection and higher employment & GDP. The purpose of imposing an appropriate carbon tax rate is to reduce carbon emissions, however a carbon tax may also reduce economic growth, and increase expenditures for firms and households. These effects will directly influence the price of labour, capital, and energy. Thus, it is very important to analyse the equilibrium of different societal units and environmental policies before setting a carbon tax. With an appropriate design, a carbon tax can be a powerful instrument for mitigation, and it can contribute to socio-economic objectives (Winkler and Marquard, 2011). Thus, in this study we defined a carbon tax formula using a 2 layer-CGE-Cobb-Douglas model4 to find the equilibrium of different societal units by combining production function and profit function for government, firm and households, respectively.
Our study used World Bank Development Indicators online database for the US from 1990 to 2014. The variables include: gross domestic product (GDP) in current US dollars (current US$); the labour force; the gross capital formation in current US dollars (current US$); energy use (kg of oil equivalent); the general government final consumption expenditure in current US dollars (current US$); households’ final private consumption expenditure in current US dollars (current US$); carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions (kg); CO2 intensity (kg per kg of oil equivalent energy use).

Literature Review

Reducing carbon emissions requires the combined efforts of all units of society, including governments, businesses, and households. Governments need to allocate funds effectively to direct markets and society towards clean energy and technologies (Jorgenson, 2014). Firms and households need to improve energy productivity, use energy more efficiently, and choose cleaner energy options (Stern, 2007). One of the best ways to connect all these units (government, firm, and household) is to put a price on carbon emissions. A carbon tax is a form of explicit carbon pricing and refers to a tax that is directly linked to the level of carbon dioxide emissions, usually expressed in terms of the value of each tonne of carbon dioxide equivalent (Marron and Toder, 2014). The purpose of a carbon tax is to tax fossil fuels based on the amount of carbon dioxide produced in the combustion process, thereby encouraging firms and households to reduce their use of fossil fuels and shift the fuel mix towards less carbon-intensive fuels and renewable energy sources (Jorgenson et al., 1992). Most of the studies have proven that a carbon tax is one of the most effective tools to reduce CO2 emissions (Jorgenson et al., 1992; Krupnick et al., 2010; Marron and Toder, 2014; Masoud and Jamal, 2017; Nordhaus, 2010; Stern, 2007; Wara, 2015).
Saboori and Sulaiman (2013b) point out that to reduce CO2 emissions, appropriate policies related to efficient energy consumption need to be put in place. In practice, a carbon tax is a consumption tax that is levied based on the carbon content of fossil fuels, which is usually expressed in a carbon price. For example, in Canada, the carbon price is a pollution tax that is imposed by increasing the cost of carbon-intensive fuels (Yukon, 2019). Carbon taxes are usually calculated based on the use of carbon dioxide equivalent units for different types of fuels. Fossil fuels include gasoline, heating oil, diesel and naphtha, the combustion of which releases carbon and other harmful greenhouse gases into the air (Poterba, 1991; Nunavut, 2019). By converting greenhouse gas emissions into CO2 equivalent units, a carbon price can be set on the relative amount of pollution produced by each fuel.

The benefits of a carbon tax

The term "taxes and dividends" has been used to describe the benefits of a carbon tax on a country’s economic cycle, where governments earn revenue by pricing pollution and redistributing that revenue through related lower taxes on revenue, wages, and sales taxes to stimulate the economy, thereby increasing public wealth. Thus, a carbon tax will reverse the cycle of economic and environmental protection, and increase GDP as CO2 is reduced (Goulder, 1995; Nordhaus, 2010; Pereira et al., 2016). The traditional "taxes and dividends” measures three levels: first, the revenue received by taxing carbon emissions (and indirectly reducing degradation of the environment); second, the carbon tax will increase employment levels and GDP; and third, the dividend suggests that the carbon tax will help reduce the public debt-to-GDP ratio (Goulder, 1995; Pearce, 1991; Pereira et al., 2016). Thus, the implementation of a carbon tax would have at least the following three benefits:
(1) A carbon tax can help governments fiscally.
The government could use the revenue from a carbon tax to control pollution, clean up the environment, improve the economic efficiency of the tax system, lower the federal budget deficit, reduce costly regulatory measures used to reduce climate disrupting greenhouse gases, and allow cuts in subsidies for clean energy technologies to make low-carbon technologies more competitive with traditional options (McKibbin et al., 2015). For example, in the US, revenue from a carbon tax is mostly used to pay for offsetting tax cuts, including cuts in labour income tax, capital income tax and lump sum transfers, reduce the budget deficit, assist individuals and firms who may be particularly hurt by the new tax, subsidise alternative energy technologies and climate adaptation, and reinforce the benefits of the carbon tax in reducing climate change (Marron et al., 2015).
Moreover, a carbon tax at certain rates would raise a significant amount of federal revenue and GDP. Rosenberg et al. (2018) considered three carbon tax scenarios that would price carbon at roughly US$14, US$50, and US$73 per tonne starting in 2020 and increasing thereafter between 1% and 3% per year until 2030. They found that a carbon tax at those rates would raise federal revenue from US$740 billion to US$3 trillion over a 10-year period. Sufficient revenue would bring increased power to a government, enabling it to enact a range of policies to reduce carbon emissions and clean up the environment. Bai and Yang (2016) studied the impact of a carbon tax on economic growth, and they found that a carbon tax has a negative impact on China’s economic growth in the short term; however, in the long term, it can promote economic growth and optimise emission reduction technologies. Andersen (2016) examined the experience of implementing a carbon tax in 14 European countries from 1991-2015 and found that carbon taxes enhanced employment and economic activity while avoiding harm to economic growth.
The effect of a carbon tax on economic growth depends on the carbon tax rate and the redistribution of carbon tax revenues. Nurdianto and Resosudarmo (2016) analysed the benefits and losses of cooperation among ASEAN members including Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand, and Vietnam in mitigating their CO2 emissions, particularly by implementing a uniform carbon tax across ASEAN nations. They discovered that the Inter-Regional System of Analysis for ASEAN members had proved that the implementation of a carbon tax scenario is an effective method of reducing carbon emissions in the region. Furthermore, they found that Indonesia and Vietnam could also gain by the implementation of a carbon tax, depending on how the revenues generated are redistributed.
In 2013, more than $28.3 billion of carbon tax revenues were collected from 40 countries and another 16 states or provinces around the world. For all the spending, more than 36% (US$10.1 billion) was paid back to corporate or individual taxpayers through tax reduction or direct rebates; 27% (US$ 7.8 billion) was used to increase energy efficiency and subsidise renewable energy. 26% (US$ 7.4 billion) went towards state general funds for fiscal purposes (Carl and Fedor, 2016).
(2) Acarbon tax can significantly reduce local pollutants and CO2 emissions.
Once the tax rate is set by the government, profits on emission-intensive products will decrease. As a result, the market will force cost-effective reductions in emission volumes or the development of more energy-efficient technologies. A carbon tax may have some additional benefits in reducing carbon emissions when the revenue from the tax is recycled. An environmental double dividend may occur when recycling carbon tax revenues reduce distortionary taxes (such as income, payroll, and sales taxes) and may have positive impacts on economic growth, employment, technological development and households (Baranzini et al., 2000). In addition, a carbon tax prices emissions to combat climate change, allowing the market to encourage households and businesses to reduce emissions to the lowest cost, and provides ongoing incentives for innovators to create renewable energy to reduce carbon emissions (Marron et al., 2015).
Davis and Kilian (2009) studied the historical variation in the US federal and state gasoline taxes, and the most credible estimates proved that a carbon tax with US$ 0.1 per gallon increase in the gasoline tax would reduce carbon emissions from vehicles in the US by about 1.5%.
Zhang et al. (2011) estimated the effect of carbon taxes on CO2 emissions of coal in 2020, using 2012 as the base year. They found that in China, when the carbon tax is CNY100, CNY150 or CNY200 per tonne of standard coal, from 2012 the consumption of coal will decrease by 4.88%, 7.31% and 9.75% in 2020, respectively. This tax will also lead to a decrease of CO2 emissions in 2020 by 8.69%, 13.02% and 17.36%, respectively.
Miller and Vela (2013) analysed the effectiveness of environmental taxes by examining the environmental performance of 50 countries using a cross-section regression and a dynamic panel regression. They found that countries with higher revenues from taxes also exhibit higher reductions in CO2 emissions, PM10 emissions, energy consumption and production from fossil sources.
Andersson (2019) analysed the effect of the environmental tax reform in 1990-1991 on carbon emissions for 25 OECD countries by using annual panel data on per capita CO2 emissions from transport for the years 1960–2005. He found that after the implementation of a carbon tax, carbon dioxide emissions from transport declined almost 11%.
(3) A carbon tax canhelp the government design and monitor long-term emissions reduction targets.
In order to achieve the greenhouse gas reduction targets, set by the EU leaders in Cyprus in October 2014, two scenarios were designed for an economy-wide carbon tax starting in 2016. First, it was predicted that a strong tax increase per tonne of CO2 per year in the EU from 2016 onwards would be sufficient to reach the reduction target in carbon emissions. Second, the carbon tax could start from a very low level and reach the target by 2016 onwards. Geometric growth by 2030 would allow for full achievement of the carbon emissions reduction target (Zachariadis, 2015).
In 2014, the Portuguese government used the carbon tax to design three target outcomes: (i) to achieve the EU’s 2030 emissions reduction targets; (ii) to promote long-term employment and GDP above pre-carbon tax levels; and (iii) to strengthen public finances by reducing public debt. Evidence presented by Pereira et al. (2016) suggests that a carbon tax is essential for Portugal if it wants to achieve a 40% reduction in CO2 emissions from 1990 levels by 2030. Moreover, in the long run, it could reduce CO2 emissions, improve macroeconomic performance, and strengthen public finances.

The negative side of a carbon tax

Double or triple dividends include simultaneous environmental and economic benefits to society through the imposition of a carbon tax (Pereira et al., 2016). The reason why double or triple dividends are very difficult to obtain is that there are many different kinds of taxes which are imposed on firms and households (such as environment tax, payroll tax, income tax, sales tax), and it is very difficult to set the right price for an equilibrium between these taxes (Goulder, 1995). When a higher carbon tax is set, firms’ production costs increase and their competitiveness decreases, thus reducing GDP and employment. The relationship between carbon taxes and government revenues can be described as a "Laffer curve", i.e., the tax rate should be kept within a reasonable range, neither too high nor too low (Upmann, 2009). In addition, if income is distributed directly to households by reducing distortionary taxes, environmental gains will be offset (Jorgenson et al., 2013).
There is much evidence to suggest that irrational carbon pricing may have several negative impacts on economic growth, businesses, and households. In addition, a carbon tax may reduce the stock of fixed and working capital, and a reduction in the stock of capital may lead to reductions in GDP, household consumption, exports, and investment (Scrimgeour et al., 2004).
(1) A carbon tax has a negative effect on economic growth
Based on the Norwegian background, using a dynamic model of a competitive fossil fuel market, Rosendahl (1995) suggested that a fixed carbon tax of US$10 per barrel of oil might reduce the Norwegian petroleum wealth of the average oil producer by 47%-68% and the reduction may correspond to a yearly income loss of about 3% of Norwegian GDP.
Malaysia has made a carbon tax proposal to reduce CO2 emissions by 2020 up to 40% of the baseline level in 2005. Othman and Yahoo (2014) calculated that under scenario 1, when only a carbon tax was examined, Malaysia’s GDP growth would decrease by 1.63%; under scenario 2, when a compensation policy was added, Malaysia’s GDP growth would decrease by 0.6%.
Meng et al. (2015) simulated the effects of a carbon tax of US$23 per tonne of carbon dioxide on economic growth in Australia and found that the carbon tax could cut CO2 emissions effectively, but would cause a mild economic growth contraction.
(2) A carbon tax may influence industry and firms negatively
The carbon tax has been converted to a cap-and-trade mechanism in the European Union, and is known as an emissions trading scheme (ETS). The ETS, the world’s most successful greenhouse gas emissions trading scheme, was established in 2005. Based on the European Commission’s report, 31 countries joined the scheme - all 28 EU member states plus Iceland, Norway, and Liechtenstein. As such, a cap-and-trade mechanism in carbon emissions permits policymakers to cap the total amount of CO2 emissions allowed. Firms are either allocated ETS or they buy these certificates in the market at the prevailing price to emit CO2. This aims to allocate a limited amount of CO2 quota to the most efficient firms which produce more goods and services at the lowest CO2 emissions. This trading scheme provides a market mechanism for CO2 emissions in EU countries. The market determines the price of CO2 per tonne, this influences the producer’s choice of energy and efficiency of energy use (Ellerman et al., 2007; Convery and Redmond, 2007; Oberndorfer and Rennings, 2007). According to the European Commission’s Climate Action Report 2015, the EU aims to reduce greenhouse gas emissions by 20% before 2020, compared with greenhouse gas emissions in 1990.
However, the EU’s ETS may decrease the profit of the EU’s ETS regulated firms. These firms must buy ETS, which may increase the price of unit material or per unit of production of goods and services. Commins et al. (2011) found that EU ETS had a significant negative effect on return-on-capital for 162,711 European corporations during 1996 to 2007. Chan et al. (2013) showed that unit material costs increased by 5% during 2005 to 2007, and 8% during the period 2008 to 2012 in the EU region.
ETS in the EU region may reduce market competitiveness for regulated firms, compared with firms in the region which have no carbon price constraints. For example, in the international airline industry, where clear disparity can be seen in competitive advantage for carriers in the countries where no ETS is applied, such as China and the US. The introduction of ETS schemes may have unintended consequences of import substitution because domestic goods become more expensive (Martin et al., 2016) and/or create a decline in employment (Abrell, 2011).
On the other hand, Schneider and McCarl (2005) employed a price endogenous sector model for agriculture in the US. They proved that carbon tax policies to mitigate greenhouse gas emissions are likely to increase the price of fossil fuel-based energy. A chain reaction would occur in higher energy prices, following a rise in farmers’ expenditure on machinery fuel, soil tillage, fertilizer efficiency, irrigation water, farm chemicals, and grain drying.
Zhao et al. (2018) found that high pressure on energy costs decreases the willingness of firms which are not part of the Carbon Tax Pilot Program in China to pay a carbon tax. These companies will choose to avoid paying a carbon tax by transferring the tax cost to labour and/or material. On examining manufacturing firms, they found that only companies involved in the non-ferrous, chemical, paper-making, and iron and steel sectors tend to pay a higher price for energy in China.
Furthermore, a carbon tax is unlikely to become a market mechanism for CO2 emissions reduction. Mardones (2018), in an analysis of the impact of a carbon tax on emissions reduction, found that at a carbon tax below US$10/tonne or in excess of US$30/tonne, the emission levels stagnate, and a carbon tax provides no real benefit in CO2 reduction. The carbon tax works only between the range of US$10/tonne and US$30/tonne.
Using the latest input-output (IO) tables from Statistics Canada for 2015, McKitrick et al. (2019) estimated the impacts of a nation-wide carbon tax using a price of Canadian $50 per tonne on domestic commodity prices. They found that production cost would increase by 2.4% for all industries within the whole economy. They estimated that by 2022, Canadian businesses would become less competitive as a result of higher energy costs, and firms may relocate to countries where climate change policies are less stringent than under a tax rate of Canadian $50 per tonne.
Pang (2019) indicated that the transfer of profits from an emission tax to a society would increase the demand for polluting products and decrease the carbon emission reduction effort for firms.
(3) A carbon tax may negatively influence households.
As a carbon tax is a cost for all consumers, it may increase the wealth gap and decrease consumption level. Liang and Wei (2012) examined the relationship between a carbon tax, the urban–rural gap and people’s living standards in China. They found that a carbon tax would increase the wealth gap between those living in the cities and those in rural areas. A carbon tax was also found to decrease the living standards for both groups.
From the perspective of consumer demand, a carbon tax is equivalent to an indirect tax reflecting the CO2 intensity of consumer goods, thus goods that generate high CO2 emissions in production will be taxed relatively heavily (Symons et al., 1994). For example, a carbon tax may lead to large increases in the prices of household energy, petrol, and transport, with small increases in the prices of food. Consequently, a carbon tax may affect the living standards of low-income households within the economy.
Environmental degradation is a major issue for human survival, and it will accompany human development for a long time to come. The advantages and disadvantages of a carbon tax are clear in the literature; too high a tax will affect the economy, and too low a tax will be particularly ineffective. How to balance a carbon tax with other taxes and fees and use it to achieve a long-term emission reduction goal becomes important and complex.

Nature of data and measurement

The annual data of eight exogenous variables Y , G , H ,   L , K , E , C ,   θ C from 1990 to 2014 was obtained from the World Bank Development database (2020) (Table 1). The variable Y is the gross domestic product (GDP) in current US dollars (current US$). Variable L is the labour force. Variable K is the gross capital formation in current US dollars (current US$). Variable E is energy use (kg of oil equivalent). Variable G is the general government final consumption expenditure in current US dollars (current US$). Variable H is the household final private consumption expenditure in current US dollars (current US$). Variable C is carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions (kg). Variable θ C is CO2 intensity (kg per kg of oil equivalent energy use), derived from the CO2 emissions divided by the energy use.

Methodology

Many studies have confirmed the role of carbon taxes in reducing carbon emissions, an inappropriate carbon tax may also increase business and household expenditures, thereby reducing economic growth. In turn, these effects would have a direct impact on the prices of labor, capital, and energy. Consequently, it is important to analyse the balance between different social units and environmental policies before setting an appropriate carbon tax rate. Indeed, with proper design, a carbon tax can be a powerful mitigation tool that helps achieve socioeconomic goals.
In his book The Economics of Welfare written in 1920, Pigou introduced a tax on pollution as an externality of market activity. He mentioned that negative externalities associated with economic activities, such as pollution, should be taxed to reduce the damage to society. This tax, known as the Pigovian tax, was to be set by the government at a level theoretically equal to the marginal social cost of the externality.
In practice, such an approach has been proved to not be feasible because of the difficulty of marginal social cost measurement (Baumol and Oates, 1971). Consideration of the appropriate use of environmental unit taxes is expressed as a least-cost measure to achieve a specific set of environmental quality standards. Thus, Baumol and Oates (1971) designed a minimised environmental tax model : min i [ 1 , , m ] c j = τ w j + p 1 x 1 j + + p i x i j + + p m x m j . Where, variable w j represents the quantities of the waste or the emissions of pollutants that the firm j discharges; variable p i represents the price of input i; the variable x i j represents the quantity of input i ( = 1,2 , , m ) used by firm j ( = 1,2 , , n ) . Then with a fixed environmental tax rate τ per unit on the emissions of pollutants, firm j can minimise the cost of whatever output their firm produces.
An environmental tax would minimise the costs to society and at the same time achieve an environmental greening objective when a wasted externality to society exists. Baumol (1972) further explained that to solve the usual pollution problem of an externality, it is necessary to set up a standard for the level of pollution, as a maximum threshold5 that is tolerable, and design tax rates and effluent charge rates that are sufficient to achieve the selected standards of acceptability.
Following Baumol and Oates (1971), many scholars have optimised the formula of a carbon tax. Symons et al. (1994) defined a carbon tax formula for different goods as t i = α c i , here i represents the i t h goods category, α represents the equivalent tax on CO2 emissions, c i represents the CO2 intensity for the i t h goods category. If k represents the k t h good within the i t h commodity group, c i k represents the CO2 intensity for good i k , the carbon tax was defined as t i k = α c i k . Similarly, Li and Jia (2017) defined the formula, T a x i = p _ e n X C O 2 , p _ e n E N E i , p _ e n P T A X , to calculate a carbon tax. Where, p _ e n represents primary energy, i represents one of the sectors, P T A X represents the carbon tax rate at the unit price of CO2 emissions, E N E i , p _ e n represents the primary energy p _ e n of the i t h sector, X C O 2 , p _ e n represents the CO2 emissions of the primary energy p _ e n . These formulas divided carbon tax into a more detailed classification, but this leads to the difficulty of pricing carbon and double counting the tax, based on crossover use of energy. As a result, the fiscal neutral6 will disappear.
Tol (2012) defined a Leviathan carbon tax rate with a theoretical upper limit as a maximum threshold to protect the fiscal neutral for climate policy when the carbon tax replaces all other taxes. The Leviathan carbon tax is formulated as t = T / M = τ Y / M , here M represents the CO2 emissions in tonne per year (tCO2/year), τ represents the total tax take in percent (%), Y represents the gross domestic product (GDP) in dollars per year ($/year), t represents the carbon tax rate in dollars per tonne of CO2 emissions ($/tCO2), T represents the total carbon tax in dollars per year ($/year). Once the maximum tax amount is set, the fiscal neutral will be achieved.
In addition, carbon taxes can be added to the retail price of fuel. Andersson (2019) uses the example of Sweden to explain the calculation of the retail price of fuel when energy and carbon taxes are considered. Assume that the variable p t , e x c l u s i v e is the tax-exclusive price; variable p t , e n e r g y is the energy tax price; variable p t , C O 2 is the carbon tax price; variable V A T t is the value added tax applied to all components of a retail price including the production cost of the fuels, the producer’s margin, and any added excise taxes; variable p t * is the retail price of gasoline and diesel. Then the retail price of fuels can be written as p t * = ( p t , e x c l u s i v e + p t , e n e r g y + p t , C O 2 ) V A T t . In practice, the average carbon tax rate was US$132 /tonne in Sweden in 2018, which is the world’s highest CO2 tax imposed on non-trading sectors and households.
An appropriate carbon tax, which is designed to reduce carbon emissions, may also reduce economic growth and increase spending by firms and households. These effects will directly affect the prices of labour, capital, and energy. Therefore, it is important to analyse the balance between different social units and environmental policies before setting a carbon tax rate. A carbon tax can be a powerful mitigation tool that can help achieve socio-economic goals (Winkler and Marquard, 2011). Accordingly, this study defines carbon tax formulas for different equilibrium social units using a two-layer CGE Cobb-Douglas model by combining the production and profit functions of government, firms, and households, respectively.
To achieve the target of CO2 emissions reduction under the equilibrium of labour, capital, energy, and carbon price, it is very important to analyse the equilibrium between economic growth and environmental policy before setting a carbon tax rate. Followed by Bonetti and FitzRoy (1999) and Lai (2016), this research defined three profit functions and a Cobb-Douglas production function for government (G), firms (F) and households (H). Also, this study used a two-layer CGE Cobb-Douglas model to estimate the endogenous variables. The structure of the relationship between labour, capital, energy, firms, government, and households is shown in Figure 3 below:
Carbon pricing
When all the energy related products are produced by firms, in making these products the total energy E is the input of firms’ production procedures. Where variable C represents the total carbon emissions with a unit of kg, θ C represents the carbon intensity of energy. The relationship between these three variables is:
θ C = C E ,   or   C = θ C E
The carbon intensity θ C represents the emission rate of carbon pollution relative to the intensity of energy. If θ C   increases, that same unit of energy would translate into more pollution, leading to a decline in environmental quality. The converted carbon emission from energy price P E ($US/kg oil) into price of carbon P C ($US/kg CO2) is expressed as follows:
P C = P E θ C ,   or   P E = θ C P C
When the price of energy P E is fixed, the higher carbon intensity θ C instead dilutes the price of CO2. Thus, when environment pollution increases due to an increase in energy pollutants conversion rate θ C , the carbon price P C will decrease. This means that for a fixed unit of energy (E), more carbon emissions (C) pollutants, unit carbon price ( P C ) would decrease. Then the total carbon tax T C with a unit of $US/kg CO2 can be defined as:
T C = τ C P C
Where, τ C is the carbon tax rate as a percentage of the energy price, and its value can be greater than 1, P C is energy converted into carbon price. Equations (1) to (2) can be rewritten as:
T C C = τ C P C C = τ C ( P E θ C ) ( θ C E ) = τ C P E E
Firm
Variable Y represents the total output of an economy; variables L , K , E are three input factors of labour, capital, and energy; the parameters α , β , γ are three proportional coefficients representing respectively the coefficients of output elasticity of labour, capital, and energy. Where, α > 0 ,   β > 0 , γ > 0 and α + β + γ = 1 , the production function of firms can be defined as a Solow-Swan CD model with the combination of Equations:
Y = Y L , K , E = e Y 0 ( x ) L α K β E γ
Where Y 0 ( x ) is a time related function which represents technical progress, because most of the economic variables have a time trend, it is necessary to design the technical progress function Y 0 ( x ) as a time trend function. Thus, different from the static technology level used in the previous research (Solow, 1956; Swan, 1956; Mankiw et al., 1992; Bonetti and FitzRoy, 1999; Masanjala and Papageorgiou, 2004; Aghion et al., 2013; Dissou et al., 2015; Huynh, 2016), this study uses the Chebysheve polynomial to estimate the dynamic technical progress Y 0 ( x ) and related coefficient of output elasticity for all three production functions.
On the other hand, firms’ profit function can be defined as:
π F = Y P L L P K K ( 1 + τ E + τ C ) P E E
Where the variables P L , P K are prices of input factors L , K ; variables τ L , τ K , τ E , τ C are tax rates of factors L , K , E , C . Then firms’ revenue ( π F ) can be derived from the sales of goods and services after costs and taxes. P L L is the labour cost paid to employees; P K K is the capital cost paid for capital investment; in this study the price of energy is separated into three parts: (1) energy price with no taxes: P E E ; (2) energy tax: τ E P E E ; (3) carbon tax: τ C P E E . Thus, ( 1 + τ E + θ C ) P E E is the total energy related cost paid to produce energy related goods.
Based on the nature of the Cobb-Douglas function, for any coefficient λ ( λ > 1 ) :
Y λ L , λ K , λ E = ( λ ) α + β + γ Y L , K , E = λ Y
When Y   and π F have continuous first partial derivatives and variable λ Y is a Lagrange multiplier, then the Lagrange function is defined as:
L L , K , E , Y , λ Y = π F λ Y ( Y e Y 0 ( x ) L α K β E γ )
Then from analysing the first order condition for L , K , E , Y , when λ Y = 1 :
P L = α Y L ,   or   α Y = P L L
P K = β Y K ,   or   β Y = P K K
( 1 + τ E + θ C ) P E = γ Y E ,   or   γ Y = ( 1 + τ E + θ C ) P E E
Household
Variable H is the expenditure of the household; the parameters m   and   n are two proportional coefficients representing the coefficient of output elasticity of labour and capital, respectively. Where m > 0 , n > 0 and m + n = 1 , then the household production function can be defined as:
H = H L , K = e H 0 ( x ) L m K n
Household profit function can be expressed as:
π H = 1 τ L P L L + 1 τ K P K K H
Household revenue ( π H ) is derived from wages and capital interest after tax and expenditure. τ L P L L is the personal income tax from employment; τ K P K K is the interest tax from capital loans; the cost item H is the expenditure of the household. Here, both H and π H have continuous first partial derivatives. Variable λ H is a Lagrange multiplier, and the Lagrange function is defined as:
L L , K , H , λ H = π H + λ H ( H e H 0 ( x ) L m K n )
Then from analysing the first order condition for L , K , H , when λ H = 1 :
τ L = 1 m H P L L
τ K = 1 n H P K K
Government
Variable G is the expenditure of government; the parameters ξ , ζ , ς , are three proportional coefficients representing respectively the coefficient of output elasticity of labour, capital, and energy. Where, ξ > 0 , ζ > 0 , ς > 0 , and ξ + ζ + ς = 1 , the production function of government can be defined as a Cobb-Douglas function:
G = G L , K , E = e G 0 ( x ) L ξ K ζ E ς
Government profit function (Upmann, 2009) can be defined as:
π G = τ L P L L + τ K P K K + ( τ E + τ C ) P E E G
Where government revenue ( π G ) is derived from all taxes after expenditure (G), the Lagrange function for λ G is defined as:
L L , K , E , G , λ G = π G + λ G ( G e G 0 ( x ) L ξ K ζ E ς )
Then from the first order condition of variables L , K , E , G when λ G = 1 :
τ L = ξ G P L L ,   or   ξ G = τ L P L L
τ K = ζ G P K K ,   or   ζ G = τ K P K K
τ E + θ C P E = ς G E ,   or   ς G = τ E + θ C P E E
(1) Market clearing conditions for governments, firms, and households
Based on the Equation (11) and (12), we achieve:
1 + τ E + τ C τ E + τ C = γ Y ς G
1 τ E + τ C = γ Y ς G 1 = γ Y ς G ς G
Assuming that the variable τ E & C is the composite energy tax rate, which includes both the energy tax rate τ E and the carbon tax rate τ C , then Equations (23) and (24) can be rewritten as:
τ E & C = τ E + τ C = ς G γ Y ς G
P E = ς G τ E + τ C E = ς G τ E & C E = γ Y ς G E
On the other hand, based on Equations (9), (10), (20) and (21):
α Y = P L L = m H + ξ G ,   or   m = α Y H ξ G H
β Y = P K K = n H + ζ G ,   or   n = β Y H ζ G H
Thus Equations (25) and (26) can be rewritten as:
  ( α + β ) Y = ( m + n ) H + ( ξ + ζ ) G
Because α + β + γ = 1 , m + n = 1 and ξ + ζ + ς = 1 , then:
( 1 γ ) Y = H + ( 1 ς ) G
γ Y ς G = Y H G ,
Thus Equations (27) and (28) can be rewritten as:
τ E & C = τ E + τ C = ς G γ Y ς G = ς G Y H G
P E = ς G τ E + τ C E = ς G τ E & C E = γ Y ς G E = Y H G E
Then:
ς = 1 1 γ Y G + H G
In isolating both variables τ E and τ C   from τ E & C , variable η represents the ratio between the real carbon tax rate τ C and the energy tax rate τ E as:
η = τ C τ E ,   or   τ C = η τ E
Then the composite energy tax rate can be rewritten as:
τ E & C = τ E + τ C = 1 + 1 η τ C = ( 1 + η ) τ E
Thus, the carbon tax rate can be rewritten as:
τ C = τ E & C 1 + 1 η = 0 , η = 0 Energy   tax   only τ E & C 1 + 1 η η > 0 τ E & C η = Carbon   tax   only
And the energy tax rate can be rewritten as:
τ E = τ E & C 1 + η = τ E & C , η = 0 Energy   tax   only τ E & C 1 + η η > 0 0 η = Carbon   tax   only
Because there is:
1 1 + 1 η + 1 1 + η = 1
Then Equation (36) can be rewritten as:
τ E & C = τ E + τ C = 1 1 + η τ E & C + 1 1 + 1 η τ E & C ,   τ C τ E & C ,   τ E τ E & C
Then the variable E and C can be expressed as:
E = ς G τ E + τ C P E = ς G τ E & C P E = ς G 1 + 1 η τ C P E = ς G ( 1 + η ) τ E P E
C = θ C E = ς θ C G τ E & C P E = ς θ C G ( 1 + η ) τ E P E = ς θ C G 1 + 1 η τ C P E = ς G 1 + 1 η τ C P C
Based on Equations (1) and (2):
τ C = T C P C = T C θ C P E
Then Equation (40) can be rewritten as:
C = ς G 1 + 1 η T C
(2) Dynamically obtaining the target for control of CO2 emissions
Assume C t q with η t q is the CO2 emissions at time t q and C t ( < C t q ) with η t is the controlled target CO2 emissions at time t . For example, if t-q is the year 2006, then t is the year 2005 and q=-1. If variable ϕ t ( ϕ t > 0 ) is the goal of decreasing rate of CO2 emissions from the time t q to time t , then there is a relation:
C t = ( 1 ϕ t ) C t q
Here the CO2 emissions C t q at time t q is a reference threshold of the reduction of CO2 emissions. If the relationships of C t q with η t q and C t with η t are considered, then Equation (42) can be rewritten as:
C t = ς θ C , t G t ( 1 + η t ) τ E , t P E , t = ( 1 ϕ t ) ς θ C , t q G t q ( 1 + η t q ) τ E , t q P E , t q
Then there is a relation between ϕ t and η t :
ς θ C , t G t ( 1 + η t ) τ E , t P E , t = ς θ C , t q G t q ( 1 ϕ t ) ( 1 + η t q ) τ E , t q P E , t q
Thus:
1 + η t = ς θ C , t G t τ E , t q P E , t q ( 1 + η t q ) ς θ C , t q G t q τ E , t P E , t ( 1 ϕ t )
η t = θ C , t G t τ E , t q P E , t q 1 + η t q θ C , t q G t q τ E , t P E , t ( 1 ϕ t ) θ C , t q G t q τ E , t P E , t ( 1 ϕ t )
1 η t = θ C , t q G t q τ E , t P E , t ( 1 ϕ t ) θ C , t G t τ E , t q P E , t q 1 + η t q θ C , t q G t q τ E , t P E , t ( 1 ϕ t )
1 + 1 η t = θ C , t G t τ E , t q P E , t q 1 + η t q θ C , t G t τ E , t q P E , t q 1 + η t q θ C , t q G t q τ E , t P E , t ( 1 ϕ t )
Then Equation (44) can be rewritten as:
C t = 1 1 + 1 / η t ς G t T C , t = θ C , t G t τ E , t q P E , t q 1 + η t q θ C , t q G t q τ E , t P E , t ( 1 ϕ t ) θ C , t G t τ E , t q P E , t q 1 + η t q ς G t T C , t
T C , t = ( 1 θ C , t q G t q τ E , t P E , t 1 ϕ t θ C , t G t τ E , t q P E , t q 1 + η t q ) ς G t C t
Assume that the expectations of:
E t ( θ C , t ) = θ C , t q ,   E t ( G t ) = G t q ,   E t ( τ E , t ) = τ E , t q ,   E t ( P E , t ) = P E , t q
If η t q 0 , then:
E t ( η t ) = η t q + E t ( ϕ t ) 1 E t ( ϕ t ) ,   or 1 + E t ( η t ) = 1 + η t q 1 E t ( ϕ t ) ,   or   E t ( ϕ t ) = E t ( η t ) η t q 1 + E t ( η t )
1 E t ( ϕ t ) 1 + η t q = 1 1 + E t ( η t )
E t ( T C , t ) = 1 1 E t ϕ t 1 + η t q ς E t G t E t C t = 1 1 1 + E t η t ς E t G t E t C t
Thus:
E t T C , t = E t η t 1 + E t η t ς E t G t E t C t = E t η t 1 + E t η t ς G t q E t C t
If η t q = 0 , then:
E t ( ϕ t ) = E t ( η t ) η t q 1 + E t ( η t ) = E t ( η t ) 1 + E t ( η t )
E t ( ϕ t ) = E t ( η t ) η t q 1 + E t ( η t ) = E t ( η t ) 1 + E t ( η t )
Thus:
E t ( T C , t ) = E t ( ϕ t ) ( ς E t ( G t ) E t ( C t ) ) = E t ( ϕ t ) ( ς G t q E t ( C t ) )
(3) 
Clean energy
When the consumption of fossil fuel energy decreases, clean energy will offset the reduction in fossil fuel energy. As a result, it is necessary to calculate how much clean energy will be needed. Assume Δ E t is the increased clean energy, then:
Δ E t = C t θ C , t C t θ C , t q = E t C t θ C , t q = E t θ C , t q E t θ C , t θ C , t q
Then the increased clean energy will be:
Δ E t = E t ( 1 θ C , t θ C , t q )
From time t q to time t , the reduced fossil energy will be replaced by clean energy in value of Δ E t .
(4) 
Parameters maximum likelihood estimation (MLE)
To find the essential parameters, maximum likelihood estimation (MLE) is generally used in the literature. Also, to improve the accuracy of the parameter estimation, a dynamic variance is essential. The GARCH(1,1) model (Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity) is a good choice for getting a dynamic variance σ t . Assuming variable ω 0 > 0 , ω 1 0 , ω 2 0 , and ω 1 + ω 2 < 1 , then the model of GARCH(1,1) is:
σ t 2 = ω 0 + ω 1 a t 1 2 + ω 2 σ t 1 2 ,   a t ~ N ( 0 , 1 )
Full maximum likelihood estimation (MLE) is based on the normal density distribution function as:
f ( a t ) = 1 2 π σ t e 1 2 ( a t σ t ) 2 ,   a t ( , )
The logarithm value of f ( a t ) is:
l n f ( a t ) = 1 2 ( l n 2 π + l n σ t 2 ) 1 2 ( a t σ t ) 2
Then the log maximum likelihood estimation for variable a t is defined as:
( a t ) = 1 2 ( l n 2 π + l n σ t 2 ) 1 2 ( a t σ t ) 2 ln | a t | l n a t 2
This study adds item ln | a t | l n a t 2 to improve the accuracy of parameters estimation. In estimating all the parameters of the three kinds of models, three steps should be taken. The market clearing conditions will be considered as controlling conditions and they are applied to the MLE procedures.
The first step is to estimate the parameters of the production function of firms. Assuming that the time series variable Y t represents GDP; time series variables L t ,   K t ,   E t represent the input factors of labour, capital, and energy; the parameters α , β , γ are three proportional coefficients which satisfy the conditions of α > 0 ,   β > 0 , γ > 0 , and α + β + γ = 1 . Assuming that the time variable t = 1990 ,   1991 ,   ,   2014 ; correspondingly, assuming that the Chebyshev polynomial independent variable is x , according to the formula x t = [ 2 ( t a ) / ( b a ) ] 1 , then x t = 1 , 0.916667 ,   , 1 .
If the variable a t represents the residual item, then the firm production regression model will be:
l n Y t = y 0 T 0 ( x t ) + y 1 T 1 ( x t ) + y 2 T 2 ( x t ) + y 3 T 3 ( x t ) + α l n L t + β l n K t + γ l n E t + a t
The second step is to estimate the parameters of government expenditure function. Assuming that the time series variable G t represents government expenditure; the parameters ξ ,   ζ ,   ς are three proportional coefficients, which satisfy the conditions of ξ > 0 , ζ > 0 , ς > 0 , and ξ + ζ + ς = 1 .
Consider the government expenditure regression model:
l n G t = g 0 T 0 ( x t ) + g 1 T 1 ( x t ) + g 2 T 2 ( x t ) + g 3 T 3 ( x t ) + ξ l n L t + ζ l n K t + ς l n E t + a t
After obtaining the parameters α ,   β , γ in the first step, considering the market clearing condition, the parameter ς is already known. This condition should be considered in this step.
The third step is to estimate the parameters of the household expenditure function. Assuming that the time series variable H t represents household expenditure, the parameters m , n are two proportional coefficients, which satisfy the conditions of m > 0 , n > 0 , and m + n = 1 . Consider the household expenditure regression model:
l n H t = h 0 T 0 ( x t ) + h 1 T 1 ( x t ) + h 2 T 2 ( x t ) + h 3 T 3 ( x t ) + m l n L t + n l n K t + a t
After obtaining the parameters ξ ,   ζ ,   ς in the second step, considering the market clearing conditions, the parameters m , n are already known.
Thus, technical progress functions for the production function of firm (Y), expenditure function of government (G) and expenditure function of household (H) can be represented by three Chebysheve functions as follows:
e Y 0 ( x ) = e y 0 T 0 ( x ) + y 1 T 1 ( x ) + y 2 T 2 ( x ) + y 3 T 3 ( x )
e G 0 ( x ) = e g 0 T 0 ( x ) + g 1 T 1 ( x ) + g 2 T 2 ( x ) + g 3 T 3 ( x )
e H 0 ( x ) = e h 0 T 0 ( x ) + h 1 T 1 ( x ) + h 2 T 2 ( x ) + h 3 T 3 ( x )

Empirical results

Estimating the technology progress parameter A (t)
The first step in this empirical study is to determine the technological progress function A ( t ) , which is e Y 0 ( x ) in Equation (5), e H 0 ( x ) in Equation (12) and e G 0 ( x ) in Equation (17). The hypothetical parameter A ( t ) = A ( 0 ) e g t for the Solow-Swan CD model with an exogenous growth rate g is difficult to determine. Many researchers have tried to determine this value in many different ways, for example, Masanjala and Papageorgiou (2004) assumed that the technology progress parameter A ( t ) can be defined as a constant as an exogenous variable, the implicit value is as unit A ( t ) = 1 and g = 0 . Aghion et al. (2013) assumed that the technology progress parameter A ( t ) may be both exogenous and endogenous, which depends on the relationships between labour and capital taxes. Dissou et al. (2015) assumed that the technology progress parameter A ( t ) is an endogenous variable, which can be estimated by a linear ordinary least squared (OLS) regression. Huynh (2016) assumed that the technology progress parameter A ( t ) can be defined by the total factor productivity (TFP) in a country; its dynamic value can be regressed by an autoregressive model as A R ( 1 ) as A t = ρ a A t 1 + ε t 1 . Atalla and Bean (2017) used a similar way to assume that the technology progress parameter A ( t ) can be replaced by the energy intensity that is a ratio of economic output per unit of energy use. However, the energy intensity varies rapidly, making the parameter A ( t ) unstable. For example, Torrie et al. (2016) proved that the total energy intensity (E/GDP) of the Canadian economy declined by 23% from 1995 to 2010, based on the development of the economy.
As there is no uniform standard in the academic community for the technological progress function, in this study it is necessary to design an appropriate function to replace the technology progress parameter A ( t ) when the issue of the relationships between the economic output and the inputs factors of labour, capital, and energy are discussed. Since neither fixed technological progress nor energy intensity is representative of output relative to the three inputs – labour, capital, and energy – this study selects a time exponential function with a third-order Chebyshev polynomial as the technological progress parameter.
Table 2 lists the production model of firms for l n Y t , the expenditure model of government for l n G t and the expenditure model of household for l n H t in the US during 1990-2014 in Equations (68) to (70).7 It is clear that all of the parameters are significant under a probability confidential level of 1%. These models are good for describing the relations between three output variables of firm’s production Y t , government expenditure G t , household expenditure H t , and three input factors of labour L t , capital K t and energy E t . For example, in firms’ production model, the estimated parameter α = 0.529271 , β = 0.195832 , and γ = 0.274897 , which refers to the output share of labour being 52.9%, the output share of capital being 19.6%, and the output share of energy being 27.5%.
When data is applied to the probability density function of Gaussian normal distribution, the variance is usually dealt with as a constant or a mean value; however, when the data are time series, the static constant variance will make a loss for estimation accuracy. The GARCH model can provide a dynamic variance series, which improves the accuracy of parameter estimation. The GARCH(1,1) model is a simple GARCH model which is usually used to provide a dynamic variance series.
Table 3 lists the three GARCH(1,1) models of the United States during 1990-2014. It is clear that the variance σ t 2 are significantly influenced by the GARCH item σ t 1 2 at a probability confidence level of 1%. The dynamic variance series has greatly improved the accuracy of MLE.
Figure 4, Figure 5 and Figure 6 depict the curves of technical progress in the US during 1990-2014. Figure 7 depicts the curves of dynamic variance for residuals from the production function of firms, the expenditure function of government and the expenditure function of household. These technical progress functions provide an explanation of how technical progress can influence economic variables through time and what the contributions of technology to economic development are.

Empirical prices of labour, capital, energy and carbon dioxide

Table 4 presents the empirical results for labour, capital, energy, and CO2 prices in the US over the period 1990-20148.
The variable P L represents the annual labour wage in the US. Thus, over the period 1990-2014, the average wage increased from US$24,737 in 1990 to US$57,722 in 2014.
The variable P K represents the annual cost of capital that a firm should pay for one dollar of capital formation in the US. The average annual price per dollar of capital formation in the US over the period 1990-2014 was $0.9308.
The variable P E represents the annual price of oil-equivalent energy in the US, which averaged US$0.9121 per kilogram in 1990 and US$1.3542 per kilogram in 2014. For comparison purposes, estimated energy prices in US$/kg have been converted to US$/barrel, US$/gallon and US$/litre.
The carbon price here is a virtual price or reference price, but it is not a real carbon price. The variable P C represents the annual carbon dioxide price of oil-equivalent energy in the US. For example, the annual carbon price of one kilogram of carbon dioxide in 1990 was US$0.2500 and the annual carbon price of one kilogram of carbon dioxide in 2014 was US$0.5712. The average carbon price was US$0.3726/kg CO2.
Figure 8, Figure 9, Figure 10 and Figure 11 depict the curves of the prices of labour, capital, energy and CO2. From 1990 to 2014, there were increases in the average US labour wage, the price of energy, and the price of carbon.

Empirical tax rates and taxes of labour, capital and energy

Table 5 lists the empirical results of tax rates and taxes of labour, capital, and energy in the US during 1990-20149.
The labour income tax rate τ L represents a percentage of a labourer’s income in one year. For example, in 1990 the labour tax rate was 6.08%, when the total labour income P L L was US$3,164,824,417,303, the total labour income tax was US$192,405,769,300. During 1990-2014 the average labour tax rate was 5.86%.
The capital income tax rate τ K represents a percentage of one dollar’s capital formation in one year. For example, in 1990 the capital tax rate was 15.78%, when the total capital formation P K K was US$1,170,995,247,561, the total capital tax was US$184,734,048,475. During 1990-2014 the average capital tax rate was 15.21%.
The composite energy tax rate τ E & C represents a percentage of values of one kilogram of oil equivalent energy in one year. For example, in 1990 the composite energy tax rate was 53.21%, when the total oil equivalent energy P E E was US$1,205,965,000,000, the total capital tax was US$641,644,553,159. During 1990-2014 the average capital tax rate was 50.43%.

The US quantified economy-wide emissions targets for the period of 2005-2050

In response to the aspirations associated with the Copenhagen Accord, Stern (2010) submitted a mitigation action plan to the Executive Secretary of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC). The US mitigation action plan set an economy-wide goal of reducing CO2 emissions. Accordingly, the US intended to achieve a short-term goal of a 17% reduction in CO2 emissions in 2020, compared to 2005 baseline year emission levels; medium-term goals of 30% and 42% reductions in 2025 and 2030, respectively; and a long-term goal of 83% reduction in 2050. Subsequently, in response to the Lima Conference’s request, the US proposed that the optimal mid-term goal is to reduce its CO2 emissions by 26%-28% from 2005 levels in 2025, and to do its best to reduce emissions by 28%.
Table 6 lists the emissions targets of the US during 2005-2050. According to the US mitigation target, when compared to the emissions level of 2005, CO2 emissions will achieve the goal ( ϕ t ) of reducing by 17% in 2020, 30% in 2025, 42% in 2030 and 83% in 2050. To achieve the 2005-2050 CO2 emissions reduction target, it is a relatively reasonable option to allocate the total emissions reduction target on an annual basis. If the emission reduction target is met each year, the total emissions reduction target will be met. The emissions reduction target from 2005 to 2050 ( ϕ t ) will be divided into a target of 1.133% in 2006, 2.267% in 2007, 80.950% in 2050, and 83.000% in 2049. In 2005 in the US, CO2 ( C t ) emissions reached 5,789,727,291,000 kg. Accordingly, CO2 ( C t ) emissions should reduce from 5,789,727,291,000 kg in 2005 to 984,253,639,470 kg in 2050; during the same period, the growth rate of CO2 emissions ( c t ) should decrease from -1.133% in 2006 to -10.761% in 2050.
Since the average growth rate of energy inputs during the period 1990-2014 was 0.6026%, it is necessary to increase the energy in the economy in order to sustain economic growth. Assuming that the average growth rate of energy inputs during the period 2015-2050 remains equal to that of 1990-2014, energy ( E t ) will increase from 2,318,707,902,000 kg oil equivalent in 2005 to 2,751,298,462,050 kg oil equivalent in 2050, while the CO2 intensity of energy ( θ t ) will decrease from 2.4969 kg CO2 /kg oil equivalent in 2005 to 0.3577 kg CO2/kg oil equivalent in 2050. Therefore, by 2050, the same unit of energy should convert to less pollution, thereby improving environmental quality.
As the CO2 intensity of energy ( θ t ) decreases and the energy equivalent of oil ( E t ) increases, the use of clean energy ( E C l e a n , t ) will provide for an increased demand for energy. As a result, clean energy ( E C l e a n , t ) will increase from 6,677,674,743 kg in 2010 to 2,353,292,653,039 kg in 2050, and the ratio of clean energy to total energy ( E C l e a n . t / E t ) will increase from 0.0030 in 2010 to 0.8553 in 2050.

Carbon tax rates for CO2 emissions reduction targets in the US during 2005-2050

Table 7 lists the carbon tax, carbon tax rate and related empirical results in the US during 2005-2050. Matching the goals of CO2 emissions reduction during 2005-2050, the results of the empirical analysis show that the reduction target will be achieved when the carbon tax ( T C , t ) of US$42.2/tonne CO2 in 2020, US$88.3/tonne CO2 in 2025, US$149.1/tonne CO2 in 2030, and US$1005.5/tonne CO2 in 2050, if only the carbon tax effort is considered. That is, when the reduction targets of CO2 emissions increased from reducing 17% in 2020 to reducing 83% in 2050, from the level of 2005, the carbon tax ( T C , t ) will increase from levying tax rate US$42.2/tonne CO2 in 2020 to a levying tax rate of US$1005.5/tonne CO2 in 2050.
Since the average price of energy for the period 1990-2014 is US$0.918344/kg oil equivalent, it is assumed that the price of energy for the period 2015-2050 will yield an average price of US$0.918344/kg oil equivalent. After obtaining the CO2 emission intensity of energy ( θ t ), the price of CO2 emissions can be estimated. When the CO2 emissions reduction target is increased from a 17% reduction in 2020 compared to 2005, to an 83% reduction in 2050 compared to 2005, the carbon price ( P C , t ) will increase from US$ 0.4306/kg CO2 in 2020 to US$ 2.5671/kg CO2 in 2050.
Because the composite energy tax ( τ E & C , t ) is shared by the carbon tax rate ( τ C , t ) and the energy tax rate ( τ E , t ), there is a balance between the carbon and energy tax rates in the relationship τ E & C , t = τ E , t + τ C , t . When the carbon tax rate ( τ C , t ) increases from 9.61% in 2020 to 22.35% in 2030 and 39.17% in 2050, the energy tax rate ( τ E , t ) decreases from 46.90% in 2020 to 30.86% in 2030 and 8.02% in 2050. In contrast, the composite energy tax rate ( τ E & C , t ) decreases from 46.90% in 2020 to 30.86% in 2030 and 8.02% in 2050.
The ratio of τ C , t / τ E & C , t and η t = τ C , t / τ E , t also shows that when the carbon tax rate increases, the energy tax rate will decrease. This implies that energy with higher carbon intensity will be subject to a higher carbon tax; however, energy with lower carbon intensity will be subject to a lower carbon tax.

Conclusion

The results indicates that, first, the CGE Cobb-Douglass models of the firm production function, the expenditure function of the government, and the expenditure function of the household are largely fitted to describe the logarithmic relationship between the two dependent variables, output and expenditure, and the three independent variables, labour, capital, and energy. Second, the application of time-dependent Chebyshev polynomial technical advances and dynamic GARCH models effectively improves the accuracy of MLE estimation, with an average residual of less than 1%. Third, in the firm production model, the estimated parameters α = 0.529271, β = 0.195832, and γ = 0.274897 refer to the output share of labour as 52.9%, capital as 19.6%, and energy as 27.5%. Fourth, when the reduction target for CO2 emissions increases from a reduction of 17% in 2020 to a reduction of 83% in 2050 from 2005 levels, the carbon tax will increase from a levy of US$42.2/tonne CO2 2020 rate to a levy of US$1,005.5/tonne CO2. Fifth, in order to achieve the US emission reduction targets the carbon price would increase from US$0.4306/kg CO2 in 2020 to US$2.5671/kg CO2 in 2050.

References

  1. Abrell, J.; Ndoye, A.; Zachmann, G. Assessing the impact of the EU ETS using firm level data. Bruegel Working Paper 2011/08, Brussels, Belgium. 2011. [Google Scholar]
  2. Aghion, P.; Akcigit, U.; Fernández-Villaverde, J. Optimal capital versus labor taxation with innovation-led growth. NBER Working Paper No. 19086. May 2013; 1–38. [Google Scholar]
  3. Andersson, J.J. Carbon taxes and CO2 emissions: Sweden as a case study. Economic Policy 2019, 11, 1–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Andersen, M.S. An introductory note on carbon taxation in Europe: A Vermont briefing; Aarhus University, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  5. Atalla, T.; Bean, P. Determinants of energy productivity in 39 countries: An empirical investigation. Energy Economics 2017, 62, 217–229. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Bai, Y.F.; Yang, X. The research on the economic effect of market-based environmental policy instruments. Open Journal of Social Sciences 2016, 4, 38–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Baranzini, A.; Goldemberg, J.; Speck, S. Survey - A future for carbon taxes. Ecological Economics 2000, 32, 395–412. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Baumol, W.J. On taxation and the control of externalities. The American Economic Review 1972, 62, 307–322. [Google Scholar]
  9. Baumol, W.J.; Oates, W.E. The use of standards and prices for protection of the environment. The Swedish Journal of Economics 1971, 73, 42–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Bloomberg New Energy Finance. Global trends in renewable energy finance 2016. 2016. Retrieved from: https://www.actu-environnement.com/media/pdf/news-26477-rapport-pnue-enr.pdf.
  11. Bonetti, S.; FitzRoy, F. Environmental tax reform and government expenditure. Environmental and Resource Economics 1999, 13, 289–308. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. BP statistic review of global energy. 2020. Retrieved from: http://www.bp.com/statisticalreview.
  13. Carl, J.; Fedor, D. Tracking global carbon revenues: A survey of carbon taxes versus cap-and-trade in the real world. Energy Policy 2016, 96, 50–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Chan, H.S.; Li, S.; Zhang, F. Firm competitiveness and the European Union emissions trading scheme. Energy Policy 2013, 63, 1056–1064. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Commins, N.; Lyons, S.; Schiffbauer, M.; Tol, N.C. Climate policy and corporate behavior. The Energy Journal 2011, 32, 51–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Convery, F.J.; Redmond, L. Market and Price Developments in the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 2007, 1, 88–111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Davis, L.W.; Kilian, L. Estimating the effect of a gasoline tax on carbon emissions. National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Paper No (14685). 2009, 1. https://www.nber.org/papers/w14685.
  18. Dissou, Y.; Karnizova, L.; Sun, Q. Industry-level econometric estimates of energy-capital-labor substitution with a nested CES production function. International Atlantic Economic Society: Atlantic Economic Journal 2015, 43, 107–121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Energy Information Administration (EIA). Energy Explained, Your Guide To Understanding. 2021. Retrieved from: https://www.eia.gov/energyexplained.
  20. Ellerman, A.; Buchner, D.; Barbara, K. The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocation, and Early Results. Review of Environmental Economics 2007, 1, 66–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Global Carbon Project. Supplemental data of Global Carbon Budget 2019 (Version 1.0). 2019. [CrossRef]
  22. Goulder, L. Environmental Taxation and the ‘Double Dividend’: A Reader’s Guide. International Tax and Public Finance 1995, 2, 157–183. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Huynh, B.T. Macroeconomic effects of energy price shocks on the business cycle. Macroeconomic Dynamics 2016, 20, 623–642. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. IPCC. United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) Emissions Gap Report. 2019. Retrieved from: https://www.unenvironment.org/resources/emissions-gap-report-2019.
  25. Jorgenson, D. Time to Tax Carbon. Harvard Magazine, 52-56 and 78-79. 2014. Retrieved from: http://bit.ly/1dDlxtI.
  26. Jorgenson, D.; Daniel, W.; Slesnick, T.; Wilcoxen, P.J. Carbon Taxes and Economic Welfare; Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics; 1992; pp. 393–431. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Jorgenson, D.W.; Slesnick, D.T.; Wilcoxen, P.J.; Joskow, P.L.; Kopp, R. Carbon taxes and economic welfare. In Brookings Papers on Economic Activity; Brookings Institution Press, 1992; pp. 393–454. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Krupnick, A.; Parry, I.; Walls, M.; Knowles, T.; Hayes, K. Towards a New National Energy Policy: Assessing the Options; Resources for the Future and National Energy Policy Institute: Washington, DC, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  29. Lai, C.F. Examining the double dividend effect of energy tax with the overlapping generations model. International Journal of Energy Economics and Policy 2016, 6, 53–57. [Google Scholar]
  30. Larsen, K.; Houser, T.; Mohan, S. Sizing Up a Potential Fuel Economy Standards Freeze. 3 May 2019. Retrieved from: https://rhg.com/research/sizing-up-a-potential-fuel-economy-standards-freeze.
  31. Liang, Q.M.; Wei, Y.M. Distributional impacts of taxing carbon in China: Results from the CEEPA model. Applied Energy 2012, 92, 545–551. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Mankiw, N.G.; Romer, D.; Weil, D.N. A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 1992, 107, 407–437. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Mardones, C.; Flores, B. Effectiveness of a CO2 tax on industrial emissions. Energy Economics 2018, 71, 370–382. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Marron, D.B.; Toder, E.J. Tax policy issues in designing a carbon tax. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2014, 104, 563–568. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Marron, D.B.; Toder, E.J.; Austin, L. Taxing carbon: What, why and how; Tax Policy Center. Urban Institute Brooking Institution, June 2015; pp. 1–28. [Google Scholar]
  36. Masanjala, W.H.; Papageorgiou, C. The Solow model with CES technology: Nonlinearities and parameter heterogeneity. Journal of Applied Econometrics 2004, 19, 171–201. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Martin, R.; Muûls, M.; Wagner, J.U. The Impact of the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme on Regulated Firms: What Is the Evidence after Ten Years? Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 2016, 10, 129–148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Masoud, Y.; Jamal, O. Carbon and energy taxation for CO2 mitigation: A CGE model of Malaysia. Environmental Development and Sustainability 2017, 19, 239–262. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. McKibbin, W.J.; Morris, A.C.; Wilcoxen, P.J.; Cai, Y.Y. Carbon taxes and U.S. fiscal reform. National Tax Journal 2015, 68, 139–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. McKitrick, R.; Aliakbari, E.; Stedman, A. The impact of the Federal Carbon Tax on the competitiveness of Canadian industries. Fraser Institute. 22 August 2019. Retrieved from: https://www.fraserinstitute.org/studies/impact-of-the-federal-carbon-tax-on-the-competitiveness-of-canadian-industries.
  41. Meng, X.M.; Siriwardana, M.; McNeill, J. The environmental and employment effect of Australian carbon tax. International Journal of Social Science and Humanity 2015, 5, 514–519. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Miller, S.J.; Vela, M.A. Are environmentally related taxes effective? Inter-American Development Bank, November 2013, IDB Working Paper Series No. IDB-WP-467, 1-27. 2013. Retrieved from: https://core.ac.uk/display/19456380.
  43. Natural Resources Defense Council. Comments of the Natural Resources Defense Council on EPA’s Proposed Emission Guidelines for Greenhouse Gas Emissions From Existing Electric Utility Generating Units; Revisions to Emission Guideline Implementing Regulations. 2018. Retrieved from: https://www.nrdc.org/sites/default/files/nrdc-ace-comments-20181031.pdf.
  44. Nordhaus, W. Carbon Taxes to Move Toward Fiscal Sustainability. The Economists’ Voice 2010, 7, 3. http://bit.ly/1LUcSxO. [CrossRef]
  45. Nurdianto, D.A.; Resosudarmo, B. The economy-wide impact of a uniform carbon tax in ASEAN. Journal of Southeast Asian Economies 2016, 33, 1–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Othman, J.; Yahoo, M. Reducing CO2 emissions in Malaysia: Do carbon taxes work? Prosiding Persidangan Kebangsaan Ekonomi Malaysia Ke 2014, 9, 175–182. [Google Scholar]
  47. Pang, Y. Taxing pollution and profits: A bargaining approach. Energy Economics 2019, 78, 278–288. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Pearce, David W. The Role of Carbon Taxes in Adjusting to Global Warming. Economic Journal 1991, 101, 938–948. [CrossRef]
  49. Pereira, A.M.; Pereira, R.M.; Rodrigues, P.G. A new carbon tax in Portugal: A missed opportunity to achieve the triple dividend? Energy Policy 2016, 9, 110–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Poterba, J.M. Tax policy to combat global warming: On designing a carbon tax. MIT Center for Energy and Environmental Policy Research, MIT-CEPR 91-003WP. March 1991. Retrieved from: https://www.nber.org/papers/w3649.
  51. Rosenberg, J.; Toder, E.; Lu, C. Distributional implications of a carbon tax. Center on Global Energy Policy, 3. 17 July 2018. [Google Scholar]
  52. Rosendahl, K.E. Carbon taxes and the petroleum wealth; International Association for Energy Economics: Cleveland, OH (United States), 1995. Retrieved from: https://www.osti.gov/biblio/416359-carbon-taxes-petroleum-wealth.
  53. Saboori, B.; Sulaiman, J.B. Environmental degradation, economic growth and energy consumption: Evidence of the environmental Kuznets curve in Malaysia. Energy Policy 2013b, 60, 892–905. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Schneider, U.A.; McCarl, B.A. Implications of a carbon based energy tax for U.S. agriculture. In Agricultural and Resource Economics Review; Cambridge University Press, 2005; Volume 34, pp. 265–279. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Scrimgeour, F.G.; Oxley, L.; Fatai, K. Reducing carbon emissions? The relative effectiveness of different types of environmental tax: The case of New Zealand. In 2nd International Congress on Environmental Modeling and Software; Osnabruck, Germany, June 2004; Retrieved from: https://scholarsarchive.byu.edu/iemssconference/2004/all/172/.
  56. Solow, R.M. A contribution to the theory of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 1956, 71, 65–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Stern, N. The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review; Cambridge University Press, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  58. Symons, E.; Proops, J.; Gay, P. Carbon taxes, consumer demand and carbon dioxide emissions: A simulation analysis for the UK. Fiscal Studies 1994, 15, 19–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Swan, T.W. Economic growth and capital accumulation. Economic Record 1956, 32, 334–361. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Tol, R.S.J. Leviathan carbon taxes in the short run: A letter. Climatic Change 2012, 114, 409–415. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Torrie, R.D.; Stone, C.; Layzell, D.B. Understanding energy systems change in Canada: 1. Decomposition of total energy intensity. Decomposition of total energy intensity. Energy Economics 2016, 56, 101–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. United Nations. Paris Agreement. 2016. Retrieved from: https://unfccc.int/sites/default/files/english_paris_agreement.pdf.
  63. Upmann, T. A positive analysis of labor-market institutions and tax reforms. International Tax and Public Finance 2009, 16, 621–646. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Nunavut. The Carbon Tax in Nunavut Frequently Asked Questions. FAQ-Carbon Tax inNunavut. July 2019. Retrieved from: https://gov.nu.ca/finance/documents/carbon-tax-frequently-asked-questions.
  65. Wara, M. Instrument choice, carbon emissions, and information. Michigan Journal of Environmental & Administrative Law 2015, 4, 261–302. [Google Scholar]
  66. Winkler, H.; Marquard, A. Analysis of the economic implications of a carbon tax. Journal of Energy in Southern Africa 2011, 22, 55–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. World Bank. Data Indicators from the Website of The World Bank. 2020. Available online: https://data.worldbank.org/indicator.
  68. Yukon. Proposed framework: Yukon government carbon price rebate. Yukon Government. 17 January 2019. Retrieved from: https://yukon.ca/en/proposed-framework-government-yukon-carbon-price-rebate.
  69. Zachariadis, T. How can Cyprus meet its energy and climate policy commitments? The importance of a carbon tax. December 2015. Cyprus Economic Policy Review 2015, 9, 3–20. [Google Scholar]
  70. Zhang, K.Z.; Wang, J.; Huang, Y.M. Estimating the effect of carbon tax on CO2 emissions of coal in China. Journal of Environmental Protection 2011, 2, 1101–1107. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Zhao, Y.B.; Wang, C.; Sun, Y.W.; Liu, X.B. Factors influencing companies’ willingness to pay for carbon emissions: Emission trading schemes in China. Energy Economics 2018, 75, 357–367. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Primary energy consumption by source (terawatt-hours (TWh), United States, 1965 to 2018.
Figure 1. Primary energy consumption by source (terawatt-hours (TWh), United States, 1965 to 2018.
Preprints 74508 g001
Figure 2. The renewable energy investment rate (as % of GDP) for nine economies in G20 in 2015.
Figure 2. The renewable energy investment rate (as % of GDP) for nine economies in G20 in 2015.
Preprints 74508 g002
Figure 3. The relationship between labour, capital, energy, firms, government and households.
Figure 3. The relationship between labour, capital, energy, firms, government and households.
Preprints 74508 g003
Figure 4. The technical progress function e x p ( Y 0 ( x ) ) impacted on the production of firms in the US during 1990-2014.
Figure 4. The technical progress function e x p ( Y 0 ( x ) ) impacted on the production of firms in the US during 1990-2014.
Preprints 74508 g004
Figure 5. The technical progress function exp ( G 0 ( x ) ) impacted on the expenditure of government in the US during 1990-2014.
Figure 5. The technical progress function exp ( G 0 ( x ) ) impacted on the expenditure of government in the US during 1990-2014.
Preprints 74508 g005
Figure 6. The technical progress function exp ( H 0 ( x ) ) impacted on the expenditure of household in the US during 1990-2014.
Figure 6. The technical progress function exp ( H 0 ( x ) ) impacted on the expenditure of household in the US during 1990-2014.
Preprints 74508 g006
Figure 7. Dynamic variance curves of σY,t, σG,t, σH,t from GARCH(1,1) models in the US during 1990-2014.
Figure 7. Dynamic variance curves of σY,t, σG,t, σH,t from GARCH(1,1) models in the US during 1990-2014.
Preprints 74508 g007
Figure 8. The estimated annual wages in the unit of US$/1 person in the US during 1990-2014.
Figure 8. The estimated annual wages in the unit of US$/1 person in the US during 1990-2014.
Preprints 74508 g008
Figure 9. The estimated capital price in the unit of US$/US$ 1 capital formation in the US during 1990-2014.
Figure 9. The estimated capital price in the unit of US$/US$ 1 capital formation in the US during 1990-2014.
Preprints 74508 g009
Figure 10. The estimated annual price of oil equivalent energy in the unit of US$/ 1 barrel in the US during 1990-2014.
Figure 10. The estimated annual price of oil equivalent energy in the unit of US$/ 1 barrel in the US during 1990-2014.
Preprints 74508 g010
Figure 11. The estimated annual carbon price in the unit of US$/ kg CO2 in the US during 1990-2014.
Figure 11. The estimated annual carbon price in the unit of US$/ kg CO2 in the US during 1990-2014.
Preprints 74508 g011
Table 1. Basic statistical data of the United States.
Table 1. Basic statistical data of the United States.
Year Y G H L K E C O 2 θ C
1990 5979589000000 947994000000 3825630000000 127939293 1283817400000 1915051008000 4823403118000 2.518681
1991 6174043000000 1004071000000 3960151000000 128695684 1238435700000 1930616357000 4820847219000 2.497051
1992 6539299000000 1049253000000 4215654000000 130848714 1309127800000 1969360943000 4909533614000 2.492958
1993 6878718000000 1074176000000 4471002000000 132277931 1398711900000 2003844644000 5028674444000 2.509513
1994 7308755000000 1109568000000 4741018000000 134617700 1550655100000 2041286993000 5094354081000 2.495658
1995 7664060000000 1144482000000 4984178000000 136503918 1625163500000 2067317182000 5132919920000 2.482889
1996 8100201000000 1176498000000 5268071000000 138422632 1752010700000 2113252684000 5252112088000 2.485321
1997 8608515000000 1224627000000 5560720000000 140843776 1925128000000 2134517436000 5368715354000 2.515189
1998 9089168000000 1272113000000 5903033000000 142834606 2076730000000 2152681199000 5401010623000 2.508969
1999 9660624000000 1357572000000 6307022000000 144820396 2252659800000 2210896395000 5504669379000 2.489791
2000 10284779000000 1444173000000 6792396000000 146767599 2424011900000 2273344129000 5693684894000 2.504542
2001 10621824000000 1545131000000 7103104000000 147741226 2342270600000 2230704586000 5595794329000 2.508532
2002 10977514000000 1651364000000 7384053000000 148568133 2368565700000 2255943576000 5641309133000 2.500643
2003 11510670000000 1755592000000 7765529000000 149183847 2493207300000 2261169559000 5675701926000 2.510074
2004 12274928000000 1868942000000 8260018000000 150258666 2765139500000 2307767983000 5756075232000 2.494217
2005 13093726000000 1980048000000 8794112000000 152118122 3040749800000 2318770902000 5789727291000 2.496895
2006 13855888000000 2089846000000 9303992000000 153992258 3232996400000 2296824886000 5697285888000 2.480505
2007 14477635000000 2209721000000 9750505000000 155294548 3235947300000 2337001704000 5789030561000 2.477119
2008 14718582000000 2368565000000 10013648000000 157089439 3059440300000 2277080529000 5614110994000 2.465486
2009 14418739000000 2442062000000 9846968000000 157204266 2525144100000 2164820311000 5263505457000 2.431382
2010 14964372000000 2522209000000 10202191000000 157015059 2752636000000 2215223615000 5395532125000 2.435660
2011 15517926000000 2530861000000 10689299000000 157131234 2877761500000 2190417726000 5289680503000 2.414919
2012 16155255000000 2544149800000 11050627000000 158429022 3126139800000 2156975857000 5119436361000 2.373432
2013 16691517000000 2523726000000 11361174000000 159007112 3298621000000 2182583138000 5159160972000 2.363787
2014 17427609000000 2562691000000 11863669000000 159800262 3510758000000 2216186625000 5254279285000 2.370865
Table 2. Three models for firms’ production, government and household expenditure in the United States during 1990-2014.
Table 2. Three models for firms’ production, government and household expenditure in the United States during 1990-2014.
l n H t h 0 = 8.381027 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) h 1 = 0.378485 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) h 2 = 0.008665 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) h 3 = 0.013608 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) m = 0.749962 ( c o n t r o l ) n = 0.249951 ( c o n t r o l )
M o d e l T 0 ( x t ) T 1 ( x t ) T 2 ( x t ) T 3 ( x t ) l n L t l n K t l n E t
l n Y t y 0 = 6.677636 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) y 1 = 0.355981 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) y 2 = 0.002686 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) y 3 = 0.018067 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) α = 0.529271 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) β = 0.195832 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) γ = 0.274897 ( p = 0.0000 * * * )
l n G t g 0 = 1.682684 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) g 1 = 0.346872 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) g 2 = 0.049443 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) g 3 = 0.108124 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) ξ = 0.202961 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) ζ = 0.194868 ( p = 0.0030 * * * ) ς = 0.602171 ( c o n t r o l )
Notes: (1) *** represents that the estimated coefficients are significant at the confidence level of 1%; (2) ς = 0.602171 is from the market clearing condition of firms, government and household; (3) m = 0.749962 and n = 0.249951 are from the market clearing condition of firms, government and household, theoretically, m + n = 1 , hear m + n = 0.999914 .
Table 3. Three GARCH(1,1) models for firms, government and household of the United States during 1990-2014.
Table 3. Three GARCH(1,1) models for firms, government and household of the United States during 1990-2014.
Variance 1 a t 1 2 σ t 1 2 Residual a t is from the equation of
σ t 2 ω 0 = 0.003188 ( p = 0.6899 ) ω 1 = 0.095786 ( p = 0.7714 ) ω 2 = 0.800057 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) l n Y t
σ t 2 ω 0 = 0.000638 ( p = 0.9992 ) ω 1 = 0.100016 ( p = 0.8593 ) ω 2 = 0.899921 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) l n G t
σ t 2 ω 0 = 0.000107 ( p = 0.9983 ) ω 1 = 0.099986 ( p = 0.8037 ) ω 2 = 0.899906 ( p = 0.0000 * * * ) l n H t
Notes: (1) *** represents that the probabilities of empirical parameters are less than the confidence level of 10%.
Table 4. Empirical results of prices of labour, capital, energy and carbon dioxide in the United States during 1990-2014.
Table 4. Empirical results of prices of labour, capital, energy and carbon dioxide in the United States during 1990-2014.
Variable P L P K P E P E P E P E θ C P C = P E / θ C
Year US $ person US $ US $ US $ kg   oil _ e US $ barrel   oil _ e US $ gallon   oil _ e US $ litre   oil _ e kg   C O 2 kg   oil _ e US $ kg   C O 2
1990 24737 0.9121 0.6297 92.5589 2.2038 0.5821 2.5187 0.2500
1991 25391 0.9763 0.6267 92.1063 2.1930 0.5793 2.4971 0.2510
1992 26451 0.9782 0.6471 95.1134 2.2646 0.5982 2.4930 0.2596
1993 27523 0.9631 0.6655 97.8151 2.3289 0.6152 2.5095 0.2652
1994 28736 0.9230 0.7143 104.9948 2.4999 0.6603 2.4957 0.2862
1995 29716 0.9235 0.7427 109.1637 2.5991 0.6866 2.4829 0.2991
1996 30972 0.9054 0.7835 115.1533 2.7417 0.7242 2.4853 0.3152
1997 32350 0.8757 0.8541 125.5426 2.9891 0.7896 2.5152 0.3396
1998 33680 0.8571 0.8891 130.6866 3.1116 0.8219 2.5090 0.3544
1999 35306 0.8398 0.9028 132.6975 3.1595 0.8346 2.4898 0.3626
2000 37089 0.8309 0.9010 132.4260 3.1530 0.8329 2.5045 0.3597
2001 38052 0.8881 0.8847 130.0405 3.0962 0.8179 2.5085 0.3527
2002 39107 0.9076 0.8609 126.5338 3.0127 0.7958 2.5006 0.3443
2003 40837 0.9041 0.8799 129.3259 3.0792 0.8134 2.5101 0.3505
2004 43237 0.8693 0.9299 136.6769 3.2542 0.8596 2.4942 0.3728
2005 45558 0.8433 1.0003 147.0323 3.5008 0.9247 2.4969 0.4006
2006 47623 0.8393 1.0719 157.5553 3.7513 0.9909 2.4805 0.4321
2007 49342 0.8762 1.0772 158.3284 3.7697 0.9958 2.4771 0.4349
2008 49590 0.9421 1.0260 150.8089 3.5907 0.9485 2.4655 0.4162
2009 48545 1.1182 0.9838 144.5980 3.4428 0.9094 2.4314 0.4046
2010 50442 1.0646 1.0112 148.6240 3.5387 0.9347 2.4357 0.4152
2011 52270 1.0560 1.0490 154.1853 3.6711 0.9697 2.4149 0.4344
2012 53971 1.0120 1.1871 174.4776 4.1542 1.0973 2.3734 0.5001
2013 55559 0.9909 1.2859 189.0063 4.5002 1.1887 2.3638 0.5440
2014 57722 0.9721 1.3542 199.0489 4.7393 1.2519 2.3709 0.5712
Notes: (1) 1 tonne = 1000 kilogram; (2) 1 barrel = 146.9819432 kg; (3) 1 US gallon = 3.499570077 kg; (4) 1 litre = 0.924414737 kg; (5) all of these units are suitable for oil equivalent; (6) oil _ e represents oil equivalent.
Table 5. Empirical results of tax rates (%) and taxes (US$) of labor, capital and energy in the United States during 1990-2014.
Table 5. Empirical results of tax rates (%) and taxes (US$) of labor, capital and energy in the United States during 1990-2014.
Variable τ L τ K τ E & C P L L P K K P E E τ L P L L τ K P K K τ E & C P E E
Year % % % US $ US $ US $ US $ US $ US $
1990 6.08% 15.78% 53.21% 3164824417303 1170995247561 1205965000000 192405769300 184734048475 641644553159
1991 6.24% 16.18% 55.34% 3267743324813 1209075575468 1209821000000 203787210875 195661682233 669488548240
1992 6.15% 15.97% 54.20% 3461062816732 1280604411336 1274392000000 212957392826 204466225065 690681642921
1993 5.99% 15.54% 51.99% 3640707527915 1347073534203 1333540000000 218015788753 209322929528 693339463917
1994 5.82% 15.11% 49.82% 3868313739302 1431288566921 1458169000000 225198982937 216219710988 726526580339
1995 5.73% 14.86% 48.61% 4056366453225 1500868677934 1535400000000 232285161783 223023345366 746415514311
1996 5.57% 14.45% 46.66% 4287203336192 1586279069562 1655632000000 238783159777 229262251199 772550246688
1997 5.46% 14.16% 45.27% 4556239311551 1685823248647 1823168000000 248551467667 238641071127 825323556542
1998 5.37% 13.93% 44.21% 4810635115451 1779950517047 1914022000000 258189271663 247894590691 846263535705
1999 5.39% 13.98% 44.47% 5113090334733 1891859924230 1996030000000 275534112072 264547846987 887688562539
2000 5.38% 13.97% 44.42% 5443437618499 2014089485282 2048210000000 293110733893 281423642964 909884781025
2001 5.58% 14.48% 46.77% 5621825839784 2080093702832 1973589000000 313601266172 301097164174 923004489802
2002 5.77% 14.97% 49.15% 5810082323130 2149749209190 1942097000000 335162417498 321798616052 954503328264
2003 5.85% 15.18% 50.17% 6092266454352 2254158248374 1989549000000 356316632105 342109356842 998198593606
2004 5.84% 15.15% 50.04% 6496766225075 2403824468897 2145968000000 379322256561 364197686932 1073904283531
2005 5.80% 15.05% 49.53% 6930132448613 2564171370116 2319566000000 401872436629 385848732392 1148970180051
2006 5.78% 15.01% 49.34% 7333522866841 2713427126635 2462050000000 424157143766 407244890020 1214804629240
2007 5.85% 15.19% 50.23% 7662595665487 2835185124081 2517409000000 448487088465 430604736244 1264421790187
2008 6.17% 16.01% 54.44% 7790121980235 2882370272076 2336369000000 480726218690 461558408098 1271969358437
2009 6.49% 16.85% 58.98% 7631423707200 2823651398920 2129709000000 495643240133 475880648915 1256181405360
2010 6.46% 16.77% 58.53% 7920211555543 2930503834750 2239972000000 511909951940 491498764412 1311082264863
2011 6.25% 16.23% 55.58% 8213191761289 3038907456348 2297766000000 513665970138 493184765576 1277189390989
2012 6.04% 15.67% 52.66% 8550511664221 3163716908993 2560478200000 516363077701 495774332413 1348458369976
2013 5.80% 15.05% 49.52% 8834339711880 3268734202564 2806617000000 512217843711 491794379734 1389909011492
2014 5.64% 14.63% 47.52% 9223932029175 3412884617211 3001249000000 520126217394 499387425892 1426111008566
Table 6. The reduction targets of CO2 emissions and empirical results in the United States during 2005-2050.
Table 6. The reduction targets of CO2 emissions and empirical results in the United States during 2005-2050.
Variable. ϕ t ϕ t ϕ t C t c t E t θ t E C l e a n , t E C l e a n . t / E t
Year Target
%
Yearly
%
% kg   C O 2 % kg   oil _ e kg   C O 2 kg   oil _ e kg   c l e a n kg   c l e a n kg   oil _ e
2005 5789727291000 0.585% 2318770902000 2.4969
2006 -1.133% -1.133% 5724112311611 -1.133% 2296824886000 2.4922
2007 -1.133% -2.267% 5658497332222 -1.146% 2337001704000 2.4213
2008 -1.133% -3.400% 5592882352833 -1.160% 2277080529000 2.4562
2009 -1.133% -4.533% 5527267373444 -1.173% 2164820311000 2.5532
2010 -1.133% -5.666% 5461652394055 -1.187% 2215223615000 2.4655 6677674743 0.0030
2011 -1.133% -6.800% 5396037414667 -1.201% 2190417726000 2.4635 8404725940 0.0038
2012 -1.133% -7.933% 5330422435278 -1.216% 2156975857000 2.4712 1495797138 0.0007
2013 -1.133% -9.066% 5264807455889 -1.231% 2182583138000 2.4122 53636018335 0.0246
2014 -1.133% -10.200% 5199192476500 -1.246% 2216186625000 2.3460 113772445532 0.0513
2015 -1.133% -11.333% 5133577497111 -1.262% 2229541365602 2.3025 153660126331 0.0689
2016 -1.133% -12.466% 5067962517722 -1.278% 2242976581871 2.2595 193628282798 0.0863
2017 -1.133% -13.600% 5002347538333 -1.295% 2256492758754 2.2169 233677399877 0.1036
2018 -1.133% -14.733% 4936732558944 -1.312% 2270090384118 2.1747 273807965439 0.1206
2019 -1.133% -15.866% 4871117579555 -1.329% 2283769948773 2.1329 314020470291 0.1375
2020 -17.00% -1.133% -17.000% 4805473651530 -1.348% 2297531946484 2.0916 354327114252 0.1542
2021 -2.600% -19.600% 4654940741964 -3.133% 2311376873993 2.0139 429043518434 0.1856
2022 -2.600% -22.200% 4504407832398 -3.234% 2325305231036 1.9371 503843352149 0.2167
2023 -2.600% -24.800% 4353874922832 -3.342% 2339317520358 1.8612 578727118144 0.2474
2024 -2.600% -27.400% 4203342013266 -3.457% 2353414247736 1.7861 653695322194 0.2778
2025 -30.00% -2.600% -30.000% 4052809103700 -3.581% 2367595921993 1.7118 728748473123 0.3078
2026 -2.400% -32.400% 3913855648716 -3.429% 2381863055019 1.6432 799204661539 0.3355
2027 -2.400% -34.800% 3774902193732 -3.550% 2396216161788 1.5754 869746823698 0.3630
2028 -2.400% -37.200% 3635948738748 -3.681% 2410655760379 1.5083 940375477679 0.3901
2029 -2.400% -39.600% 3496995283764 -3.822% 2425182371991 1.4420 1011091144681 0.4169
2030 -42.00% -2.400% -42.000% 3358041828780 -3.974% 2439796520965 1.3764 1081894349044 0.4434
2031 -2.050% -44.050% 3239352419314 -3.534% 2454498734800 1.3198 1144591381025 0.4663
2032 -2.050% -46.100% 3120663009849 -3.664% 2469289544176 1.2638 1207377008546 0.4890
2033 -2.050% -48.150% 3001973600383 -3.803% 2484169482969 1.2084 1270251765485 0.5113
2034 -2.050% -50.200% 2883284190918 -3.954% 2499139088274 1.1537 1333216188935 0.5335
2035 -2.050% -52.250% 2764594781452 -4.116% 2514198900420 1.0996 1396270819226 0.5554
2036 -2.050% -54.300% 2645905371987 -4.293% 2529349462994 1.0461 1459416199946 0.5770
2037 -2.050% -56.350% 2527215962521 -4.486% 2544591322858 0.9932 1522652877955 0.5984
2038 -2.050% -58.400% 2408526553056 -4.696% 2559925030169 0.9409 1585981403412 0.6195
2039 -2.050% -60.450% 2289837143591 -4.928% 2575351138401 0.8891 1649402329789 0.6405
2040 -2.050% -62.500% 2171147734125 -5.183% 2590870204361 0.8380 1712916213895 0.6611
2041 -2.050% -64.550% 2052458324660 -5.467% 2606482788213 0.7874 1776523615892 0.6816
2042 -2.050% -66.600% 1933768915194 -5.783% 2622189453494 0.7375 1840225099319 0.7018
2043 -2.050% -68.650% 1815079505729 -6.138% 2637990767141 0.6881 1904021231111 0.7218
2044 -2.050% -70.700% 1696390096263 -6.539% 2653887299504 0.6392 1967912581620 0.7415
2045 -2.050% -72.750% 1577700686798 -6.997% 2669879624371 0.5909 2031899724632 0.7610
2046 -2.050% -74.800% 1459011277332 -7.523% 2685968318987 0.5432 2095983237394 0.7803
2047 -2.050% -76.850% 1340321867867 -8.135% 2702153964077 0.4960 2160163700630 0.7994
2048 -2.050% -78.900% 1221632458401 -8.855% 2718437143865 0.4494 2224441698563 0.8183
2049 -2.050% -80.950% 1102943048936 -9.716% 2734818446094 0.4033 2288817818937 0.8369
2050 -83.00% -2.050% -83.000% 984253639470 -10.761% 2751298462050 0.3577 2353292653039 0.8553
Table 7. Carbon tax rates in the units of US$/kg CO2 and percentages for reduction targets in the United States during 2005-2050.
Table 7. Carbon tax rates in the units of US$/kg CO2 and percentages for reduction targets in the United States during 2005-2050.
Variable T C , t T C , t τ C , t τ E , t τ C , t / τ E & C , t τ E , t / τ E & C , t τ E & C , t P C , t η t
Year US $ kg   C O 2 US $ tonne   C O 2 % % % % % US $ kg   C O 2 Ratio
2005 0.0000 0.0 0.00% 49.53% 0.00% 100.00% 49.53% 0.4006 0.0000
2006 0.0024 2.4 0.55% 47.88% 1.13% 98.87% 48.43% 0.4301 0.0115
2007 0.0048 4.8 1.07% 46.29% 2.27% 97.73% 47.36% 0.4449 0.0232
2008 0.0072 7.2 1.74% 49.30% 3.40% 96.60% 51.03% 0.4177 0.0352
2009 0.0098 9.8 2.54% 53.45% 4.53% 95.47% 55.99% 0.3853 0.0475
2010 0.0124 12.4 3.02% 50.21% 5.67% 94.33% 53.23% 0.4101 0.0601
2011 0.0150 15.0 3.53% 48.36% 6.80% 93.20% 51.89% 0.4258 0.0730
2012 0.0177 17.7 3.69% 42.87% 7.93% 92.07% 46.57% 0.4804 0.0862
2013 0.0205 20.5 3.85% 38.63% 9.07% 90.93% 42.48% 0.5331 0.0997
2014 0.0234 23.4 4.05% 35.68% 10.20% 89.80% 39.73% 0.5773 0.1136
2015 0.0263 26.3 6.60% 51.63% 11.33% 88.67% 58.23% 0.3988 0.1278
2016 0.0293 29.3 7.22% 50.67% 12.47% 87.53% 57.88% 0.4064 0.1424
2017 0.0324 32.4 7.82% 49.71% 13.60% 86.40% 57.54% 0.4143 0.1574
2018 0.0356 35.6 8.43% 48.77% 14.73% 85.27% 57.19% 0.4223 0.1728
2019 0.0388 38.8 9.02% 47.83% 15.87% 84.13% 56.85% 0.4306 0.1886
2020 0.0422 42.2 9.61% 46.90% 17.00% 83.00% 56.51% 0.4391 0.2048
2021 0.0502 50.2 11.01% 45.16% 19.60% 80.40% 56.17% 0.4560 0.2438
2022 0.0588 58.8 12.40% 43.44% 22.20% 77.80% 55.84% 0.4741 0.2853
2023 0.0679 67.9 13.76% 41.74% 24.80% 75.20% 55.50% 0.4934 0.3298
2024 0.0777 77.7 15.12% 40.05% 27.40% 72.60% 55.17% 0.5142 0.3774
2025 0.0883 88.3 16.45% 38.39% 30.00% 70.00% 54.84% 0.5365 0.4286
2026 0.0987 98.7 17.66% 36.85% 32.40% 67.60% 54.51% 0.5589 0.4793
2027 0.1099 109.9 18.86% 35.33% 34.80% 65.20% 54.18% 0.5829 0.5337
2028 0.1220 122.0 20.04% 33.82% 37.20% 62.80% 53.86% 0.6089 0.5924
2029 0.1350 135.0 21.20% 32.34% 39.60% 60.40% 53.54% 0.6369 0.6556
2030 0.1491 149.1 22.35% 30.86% 42.00% 58.00% 53.22% 0.6672 0.7241
2031 0.1621 162.1 23.30% 29.60% 44.05% 55.95% 52.90% 0.6958 0.7873
2032 0.1761 176.1 24.24% 28.34% 46.10% 53.90% 52.58% 0.7267 0.8553
2033 0.1912 191.2 25.17% 27.10% 48.15% 51.85% 52.26% 0.7599 0.9286
2034 0.2076 207.6 26.08% 25.87% 50.20% 49.80% 51.95% 0.7960 1.0080
2035 0.2253 225.3 26.98% 24.66% 52.25% 47.75% 51.64% 0.8352 1.0942
2036 0.2447 244.7 27.87% 23.46% 54.30% 45.70% 51.33% 0.8779 1.1882
2037 0.2659 265.9 28.75% 22.27% 56.35% 43.65% 51.02% 0.9247 1.2910
2038 0.2891 289.1 29.62% 21.10% 58.40% 41.60% 50.72% 0.9761 1.4038
2039 0.3148 314.8 30.48% 19.94% 60.45% 39.55% 50.41% 1.0328 1.5284
2040 0.3432 343.2 31.32% 18.79% 62.50% 37.50% 50.11% 1.0959 1.6667
2041 0.3750 375.0 32.15% 17.66% 64.55% 35.45% 49.81% 1.1662 1.8209
2042 0.4106 410.6 32.98% 16.54% 66.60% 33.40% 49.51% 1.2453 1.9940
2043 0.4510 451.0 33.79% 15.43% 68.65% 31.35% 49.22% 1.3347 2.1898
2044 0.4969 496.9 34.59% 14.33% 70.70% 29.30% 48.92% 1.4367 2.4130
2045 0.5498 549.8 35.38% 13.25% 72.75% 27.25% 48.63% 1.5541 2.6697
2046 0.6113 611.3 36.16% 12.18% 74.80% 25.20% 48.34% 1.6906 2.9683
2047 0.6836 683.6 36.93% 11.12% 76.85% 23.15% 48.05% 1.8514 3.3197
2048 0.7701 770.1 37.68% 10.08% 78.90% 21.10% 47.76% 2.0435 3.7393
2049 0.8751 875.1 38.43% 9.04% 80.95% 19.05% 47.47% 2.2771 4.2493
2050 1.0055 1005.5 39.17% 8.02% 83.00% 17.00% 47.19% 2.5671 4.8824
1
Primary energy consumption is the same as direct method measures energy statistics in their raw form: how much coal, oil and gas energy are consumed as inputs to the energy system.
2
Despite the US return to the Paris Agreement in 2021, political factors create a great uncertainty about US environmental policy.
3
The U.S. Climate Alliance is a coalition committed to reducing GHG emissions in line with the goals of the Paris Agreement (U.S. Climate Alliance, 2019).
4
A carbon tax could reduce economic growth and increase spending by businesses and households. These effects would have a direct impact on the price of labour, capital and energy (Winkler and Marquard, 2011). In the CGE model, equilibrium is characterised by the set of prices and production levels in each industry, such that the market demand for all goods is equal to the supply. Also, the Cobb-Douglas production function was created by Cobb and Douglas (1928) to describe the relationship between manufacturing output, labour input, and capital input for the period 1889-1922 in the UK. Thus, when these two models are combined, the balance between the carbon tax and governments’, firms’ and households’ expenditure is well solved.
5
A maximum threshold of carbon tax rate is to protect the fiscal neutral, if the carbon tax rate exceeds this threshold, the fiscal neutral will disappear.
6
A fiscal neutral form of revenue neutrality is that when fiscal revenues from carbon taxes are increased, fiscal revenues from other taxes will decrease, but the government budgetary position will remain unchanged and the overall tax burden will remain the same.
7
All of the parameters are estimated by the method of maximum likelihood estimation (MLE).
8
Prices of labour, capital and energy are estimated by maximum likelihood estimation (MLE) as endogenous variables.
9
The tax rates including .  
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.
Copyright: This open access article is published under a Creative Commons CC BY 4.0 license, which permit the free download, distribution, and reuse, provided that the author and preprint are cited in any reuse.
Prerpints.org logo

Preprints.org is a free preprint server supported by MDPI in Basel, Switzerland.

Subscribe

© 2024 MDPI (Basel, Switzerland) unless otherwise stated