1. Introduction
In recent years, particularly during the pandemic, many countries have seen a consistent rise in public debt. This trend has sparked concerns about its potential effects on sustained economic growth. According to the conventional view, rooted in the Ricardian Equivalence theory, the negative impacts of rising public debt could be offset by an equal increase in private savings. This suggests that the overall national savings would remain unchanged, thus not influencing growth (e.g., Barro [
1]). Conversely, if Ricardian Equivalence is not applicable, another strand of literature believes that increased public debt could negatively affect long-term economic growth (e.g., Blanchard [
2], Elmendorf and Gregory Mankiw [
3]).
Recent studies have shifted towards exploring potential nonlinear dynamics within the debt-growth nexus, examining how accumulating debt might adversely affect economic growth, particularly when debt levels surpass certain thresholds. A seminal study by Reinhart and Rogoff [
4] posits that public debt begins to impede economic growth when the debt-to-GDP ratio exceeds 90%. Using threshold regression models, studies by Cecchetti et al. [
5], Caner et al. [
6], Afonso and Jalles [
7] identified varying thresholds of debt-to-GDP ratios—85%, 77%, and 59%, respectively—at which public debt begins to harm economic growth. However, Kourtellos et al. [
8] were unable to confirm a significant threshold effect for public debt when adjusting for endogeneity concerns.
The above-mentioned studies provide mixed evidence about the nonlinear effects of public debt on economic growth and two main challenges emerge. Firstly, these findings are obtained under strong assumptions of homogeneity in threshold levels across different countries. Commonly, heterogeneity is modeled as unit-specific, time-invariant fixed-effects. Chudik et al. [
9] examine a dynamic heterogeneous panel threshold model with cross-sectional dependent errors, yet this approach still assumes a uniform threshold level for all countries. As allowing for country-specific threshold levels is data-demanding, applied researchers face a trade-off between adopting flexible methods for modeling unobserved heterogeneity and building parsimonious specifications that can be well handled by a limited dataset. Secondly, conventional threshold regression models assume a discontinuous regression function at the actual threshold level, which may not be suitable in this context. It is not intuitively expected to observe an abrupt jump in the economic growth rate when the public debt ratio increases marginally at the turning point. Chan and Tsay [
10] introduces a continuous threshold autoregressive model, which enables a piece-wise linear function of the threshold variable. Building on this, Hansen [
11] expands the framework by proposing tests for a threshold effect and inferring the regression parameters in a continuous threshold model with an unknown threshold parameter, termed the kink threshold regression (KTR) model. This model is also applied to re-examine the issue of public debt overhang, albeit under the assumption of a uniform threshold level.
Motivated by previous studies, in this paper, we employ a panel kink threshold regression model with latent group structures to reexamine the debt-growth puzzle. Our contributions are twofold. In terms of methodology, our proposed model extends the panel threshold regression model with latent group structures of Miao et al. [
12] by incorporating a continuous threshold effect. This model enables variations in slope and threshold coefficients across individual units through a group-based pattern within a continuous threshold effect framework, effectively addressing the previously mentioned two challenges. The proposed data-driven method aligns with other studies in panel latent group structures (e.g., Bonhomme and Manresa [
13], Su et al. [
14], and Bonhomme et al. [
15]), balancing the trade-off between the limited flexibility of homogeneity assumptions and the extensive data requirements of heterogeneity inherently. We present the estimation strategy and show the latent group structure can be estimated consistently with a probability that approaches 1. This extends Theorem 3.1 from Miao et al. [
12] to the context of continuous threshold effects. Our second contribution lies in our empirical findings. By using the dataset of Chudik et al. [
9], encompassing data from forty countries spanning from 1980 to 2010, we determine that the optimal number of groups is three and recover the group structures. We observe two out of these three groups benefit significantly from increasing public debt, up to a certain threshold beyond which the significance diminishes. Our findings indicate the presence of a heterogeneous threshold effect, suggesting that any contradictory conclusions in the previous studies might stem from overlooking this heterogeneous impact on the way countries manage their debt obligations.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows.
Section 2 describes our panel kink threshold regression model and the estimation strategy.
Section 3 details the assumptions and establishes the consistency of the estimators for group membership. In
Section 4, we evaluate the finite sample performance of our model through Monte Carlo simulations. The empirical results of our study are presented in
Section 5.
Section 6 concludes the paper. Technical proofs are relegated to the appendix.
3. Asymptotic Results
In this section, we present the asymptotic results of the estimators of the group structure. Below, we list some regularity conditions used to derive the consistency of the group structure estimator.
Assumption A1. (i). For each , , where is the smallest sigma field generated by .
(ii). are mutually independence of each other across i.
(iii). For all i, are strictly stationary mixing process with mixing coefficients satisfying for some constants & .
Assumption A2. (i). For some and some constants , , , and .
(ii). The parameter space and are compact such that and .
(iii). has a density function and is continuous over and .
(iv). Let and . For some constants , as , we have
There exists a constant . such that for all
(vi). For all and , we have for some constants .
(vii). For any and , for some constants , we have
(viii). For all : .
(ix). and as .
Assumption 1 is similar to Assumptions A.1 (i)-(iii) of Miao et al. [
12] and Assumptions A.2 (a)-(c) in Su and Chen [
19] and is standard in the literature. Assumption 1 (i) assumes the martingale difference sequence condition and Assumption 1 (ii) is the cross-sectional independence. Assumption 1 (iii) imposes the strong mixing condition.
Assumptions 2 (i)-(ii) are the regularity conditions. Assumption 2 (iii) is similar to Assumption 1.4 of Hansen [
11] and requires that the threshold variable,
, has a bounded density function. Assumption 2 (iv) is a non-colinearity condition, similar to Assumption A.4(ii) in the Miao et al. [
12], but specifies that it requires to hold for each individual. Assumption 2 (v), paralleling Assumption A2 of Miao et al. [
12] and Assumption 1 (g) of Bonhomme and Manresa [
13], extends the full rank condition in the standard kink regression model to encompass cases with latent groups. Assumptions 2 (vi)-(viii) are needed for the identification and mirror Assumption A.3 (i)-(iii) of Miao et al. [
12]. Specifically, Assumption 2 (vi) requires the group-specific slope and threshold coefficients to be distinct from each other. Assumption 2 (vii) is inferred from Assumption 2 (vi). Assumption 2 (viii) ensures that each group size is sufficiently large that is asymptotically non-negligible. Assumption 2 (ix) is similar to Assumption A.3 (iv) of Miao et al. [
12] and defines the relative magnitude of individual size
N and period size
T, fitting many empirical macroeconomic applications, including ours.
Theorem 1.
Given Assumptions A1 - A2, as , we have
Theorem 1 extends Theorem 3.1 of Miao et al. [
12] to allow for the continuous threshold effect and is similar to Theorem 2 of Bonhomme and Manresa [
13]. This theorem states, as
, the probability of correctly assigning the group structure approaches 1. Therefore, given the latent group structure can be estimated at a faster rate (see Lemma A3 in the appendix for the rate of recovering latent group structure) than the convergence rate of the estimators of the slope and kink threshold parameters of the pooled panel kink regression model (see Hansen [
11]), similar to Miao et al. [
12], we can establish the estimators of the slope and kink threshold parameters of the panel kink regression model with latent groups are asymptotically equivalent to the infeasible estimators that are obtained as if the group structure is known
a priori.
2
4. Monte Carlo Simulation
In this section, we propose Monte Carlo simulations to test our estimator with a small sample size. We list the data-generating processes(DGPs) and the Monte Carlo results, where we first consider the static model, and then a dynamic model suits our empirical application. We have
where
,
,
denotes the group specified fixed effect,
and
are group specified slopes.
is the threshold value. We set the number of groups to be 3, thus
are chosen among
. We set the parameters
,
. We propose a diminishing threshold effect, with
. As following the theory, the group identification does not rely on the heterogeneous threshold effect across groups, to test that, we focus on two cases, (1) homogeneous group-specific threshold values, while we set
; (2) heterogeneous group-specific threshold values, with threshold values
. We repeat the Monte Carlo simulation 1000 times and the results are shown in
Table 1,
Table 2 and
Table 3.
Table 1 reports the Monte Carlo results for homogeneous group-specific threshold value DGP and
Table 1 shows the results for heterogeneous group-specific threshold value DGP. It is worth noting that for both DGPs with homogenous and heterogenous thresholds across groups, as seen from the mean squared error(MSE) panels, our estimator displays convergence with either the number of
N or
T increases. In
Table 3, we also report the average misclassification frequency(MF) in
Table 3 across replications, where for each replication, we define
. The estimation results show that with either
N or
T increase, we observe a decreasing misclassification frequency. In the most unfavorable scenario, the average rate of misclassification with our approach stands at approximately
, indicating the effectiveness of our proposed method. Also, with a fixed
N and
T, the estimators with homogeneous thresholds DGP have a smaller
, compared with heterogeneous thresholds DGP. This observation aligns with the results presented in [
12]. Theoretical indications from the study suggest that in threshold regression, group identification hinges on the variation in slopes across groups. The distinct threshold effects specific to each group do not contribute to the identification process.
DGP2: where
and again we keep the number of groups as 3. We set
,
and
, which suggests a dynamic model with stationary process and a diminishing threshold effect. Again, we consider two DGPs that cover both homogeneous group-specified threshold values(
) and heterogeneous group-specific threshold values(
). We repeat the Monte Carlo simulation 1000 times and report the results in
Table 4,
Table 5 and
Table 6.
Again,
Table 4 and
Table 5 report the Monte Carlo results for the homogeneous and heterogeneous group-specified threshold effect, respectively. Similar to the results in DGP1 with a static setup, the Monte Carlo results in DGP2 show convergence with either
N or
T increases. We can observe the convergence in
Table 4 with homogeneous group-specific threshold value cases and
Table 5 with heterogeneous group-specific threshold values. In
Table 6, we observe that misclassification frequency decreases as
N or
T increases.