1. Introduction
Virtual agglomeration (VA), a brand-new economic organisational form recently, originates from digital technology, which can be related back to the 1997s. But the definition of virtual agglomeration has not been clearly defined. Some scholars argue that VA, with information technology as the core, modern network as the carrier, and with a certain degree of dominance or expertise in the production of the same or similar products, is a collection of firms and related organisations that are diversified, independently owned, geographically dispersed and have certain strengths or specialisations in the production of the same or similar products [
1,
2]. The competitive advantage of virtual agglomeration depends on the level of digitization and the internetization of network nodes and channels [
3]. The global economy is undergoing a transformative shift driven by digitalization [
4]. Digital technology, internet platforms, and digital services advance, facilitate seamless connections between supply and demand. Market participants are increasingly interconnected, fostering interaction and integration across innovation, talent, technology, and industrial networks. This enhanced connectivity has led to heightened dynamism and fluidity in economic chains. Notably, concepts like reverse “distance decay” increasing returns to scale, and domain detachment challenge traditional location theories, giving rise to the notion of virtual agglomeration.
In our daily lives, the prevalence of virtual agglomeration is increasing, exemplified by platforms like Alibaba, industrial internet networks, Apple’s App Store, virtual industrial parks, Uber, virtual communities, and more. With the acceleration of technological innovation iteration, virtualization features are becoming increasingly prominent. Virtual agglomeration can achieve greater economies of scale, further optimize transaction costs, and save costs in industrial chain collaboration [
5], while reducing the congestion effect caused by geographical agglomeration [
6]. At this point, The importance of geographical proximity is questionable [
7,
8]. Other forms of proximity, such as relational, social, cognitive, organizational, and institutional, may be of more importance[
9].
As we all know, the emergence of any economic organization is inevitably the result of market competition. As an important concept in economics, total factor productivity (TFP) measures the impact of technological progress on production.TFP decomposition can be separated into scale economies, technical change, and technical efficiency change [
10]. Virtual agglomeration, which is incremental in scale, enables efficient allocation of dispersed resources and alleviates the problems of monopoly and scarcity of geographical resources, and is considered to be a new driver of total factor productivity. In this context, we consider it necessary to conduct a study on the relationship between virtual agglomeration and total factor productivity.
The relevant literature mainly includes the following aspects. The qualitative research literatures have focussed on the discussion of what virtual agglomeration is, what are its characteristics and what are its economic advantages [
1,
5,
11,
12,
13]. In the applied research literature, research on the relationship between virtual agglomeration and economic development primarily focuses on the quality of export products, export value-added rates [
14,
15], regional coordinated development [
16], Chinese urban innovation [
17], and total factor productivity [
18,
19]. In the empirical research literature, In the empirical research literature, existing literature has focused on analysing the economic role of virtual agglomeration in terms of transaction costs, economies of scale, technological innovation, labour reservoirs, knowledge spillovers and positive externalities. Some scholars have also studied the virtual agglomeration of more segmented industries, such as virtual agglomeration of producer services [
20], virtual agglomeration of creative industries [
21], and manufacturing virtual agglomeration [
22].
According to existing literature around the world, the following shortcomings are found. First,to the best of our knowledge, there has been no unified definition of virtual agglomeration in the qualitative research. Second, the academic literature has so far paid surprisingly little attention to the linkage between TFP and virtual agglomeration, which may be an important innovation driver for TFP in the empirical research. Third, there has been no scientific index system to measure virtual agglomeration, and it is important to measure the current state of virtual agglomeration development through an appropriate index. In addition, linear regressions have been widely used in previous studies, whereas we believe that the impact of the virtual agglomeration on total factor productivity is quite complicated and there may be non-linear linkages.
The contributions of this paper include the following aspects. First, Virtual agglomeration is an emerging field. he most prevalent method for measuring virtual agglomeration uses e-commerce transaction volumes to gauge locational entropy and the reciprocal of the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index [
19]. However, we believe that virtual agglomeration is a complex concept, and using a single indicator to measure it only captures one aspect of virtual agglomeration, failing to comprehensively measure its overall level and offering poor representativeness. Therefore, we have developed our own set of indicators for virtual agglomeration based on an analysis of the concept and characteristics of virtual agglomeration. Second, the subjective weighting method usually introduces uncertainty in the construction of the indicator system. We use the entropy method, which is an objective weighting method to scientifically reflect the contribution of different dimensions of evaluation elements and construct the virtual agglomeration index. Third, starting from the theory of virtual agglomeration, we analyze the mechanism by which virtual agglomeration affects total factor productivity from the perspectives of micro-mechanism resource allocation, technological advancement, and economies of scale. For the first time, we systematically explore and test the intrinsic connection between virtual agglomeration and total factor productivity. In addition, linear regressions are mostly employed in panel data analysis, but we argue that there is a nonlinear relationship between virtual agglomeration and TFP. Therefore, this paper constructs a nonlinear panel model with square terms, which is more in line with the current situation.
In our discussion, we employ a nonlinear model to describe the relationship between virtual agglomeration and TFP to demonstrate that virtual agglomeration is an driver of TFP growth. We start with the calculation of provincial TFP based on DEA-Malmquist method and the construction of virtual agglomeration index by using the TOPSIS method from 2013 to 2021 in China, which provides the panel data for our further analysis. Next, we use regressions to deal with nonlinear relationships. We propose that virtual agglomeration is an driver and discuss the mechanisms by which virtual agglomeration works in terms of resource allocation, technological progress and economies of scale. To conclude our discussion, we make some suggestions for virtual agglomeration.
2. Literature Review and Hypotheses
According to the theory of virtual agglomeration (VA), VA has transformed traditional market models and surpassed industrial location theory. It offers significant advantages, including reducing transaction costs for upstream and downstream industries, expanding industrial production scale , lowering geographical spatial costs, accelerating information dissemination [
5,
7], and generating economies of scale in demand. According to Chen Xiaoyong (2017), traditional industrial agglomeration relies on a linear division of labor based on the value chain, whereas virtual industrial agglomeration creates a value network, enabling a network-based division of labor. This not only enriches business networks and broadens the value chain but also increases the potential paths for business collaboration. The production potential will be maximized under the support of digital technologies such as AI, cloud computing, the Internet of Things, and blockchain.
With the acceleration of technological innovation, VA becomes increasingly attractive under the constraints of stringent environmental regulations due to its advantages such as borderlessness, economies of scale, network spillover effects, and transaction cost savings. Consequently, the number of VA organizations is gradually increasing. Scholars are also beginning to explore the impact of VA on economic development [
14,
15,
16,
17]. Duan and Zhang (2023) have indicated that industrial virtual agglomeration breaks free from the spatial constraints of geographical entities, integrates distributed elements through networking, achieves bidirectional feedback of information, expands the utilization of geographical space, and enhances total factor productivity [
18]. Zhang et al., (2024) also noted that VA of manufacturing is a new driving force for improving green TFP [
19]. This indicates that scholars have begun to explore the relationship between VA and TFP. However, However, the current study does not capture the key mechanism of the role of VA and TFP.
According to Solow (1957), total factor productivity (TFP) refers to the increase in output caused by technological progress and capability enhancement beyond the input of various factors such as capital and labor. Improvements in TFP primarily arise from enhancements in efficiency, technological advancements, and scale effects. Therefore, this paper seeks to investigate whether virtual agglomeration can increase efficiency, promote technological progress, enhance scale effects. Next, the paper will first conduct a theoretical exploration, followed by empirical data testing and analysis of the results.
2.1. Virtual Agglomeration Can Optimize Resource Allocation
The concept of virtual agglomeration originates from the concept of cyberspace proposed by Wilson (1967), and represents a new organizational form established by different enterprises that transcends geographical boundaries [
1]. VA, facilitated by online platforms, is characterized by its openness, inclusivity [
1] vast scale, and low barriers to entry [
5]. We believe that virtual agglomeration optimize resource allocation efficiency through the following pathways. First, virtual agglomeration overcomes geographical constraints to optimize resource allocation. It utilizes digital platforms to enable cross-regional and cross-industry resource flows and sharing, breaking down geographical limitations, enhancing the efficiency of resource mobility, and fostering synergistic effects. Second, virtual agglomeration reduces information asymmetry, thus optimizing resource allocation efficiency. Through digital platforms, information can be rapidly transmitted and shared, reducing barriers and distortions in information, enhancing transparency and collaboration in the flow of factors, overcoming the problem of information asymmetry, and optimizing the allocation of production factors within the division of labor structure [
16]. Third, virtual agglomeration lowers transaction costs, thereby optimizing resource allocation efficiency. Compared to traditional industrial agglomerations, virtual agglomerations possess dual attributes that consider both “demand” and “supply” sides [
5]. By facilitating on-demand production, they reduce search costs and optimize resource allocation. Additionally, within virtual agglomerations, the relationship between upstream and downstream enterprises shifts from production-process binding to task-based connections, leveraging the “Internet+” to automatically avoid costs of choice and coordination [
23], further enhancing resource allocation efficiency. Lastly, virtual agglomerations, unlike traditional ones, undoubtedly expand the boundaries of agglomeration, making it “boundary-less”. In the context of “breaking out” of traditional clusters, any organization or individual within the agglomeration has the opportunity to find the best partners at lower costs, achieving a relatively optimal combination, which fundamentally enhances the efficiency of resource allocation. Overall, as a product of the digital economy, VA should feature lower costs in searching, copying, transporting, tracking, and verifying [
24]. The savings on these costs enable businesses to focus more on enhancing TFP.
2.2. Virtual Agglomeration Can Promote Technology Progress
Krugman pointed out in his book Geography and Trade that industrial agglomeration has a technology diffusion effect. He also pointed out that there is a self-enhancing relationship between industrial agglomeration and technology diffusion that is interrelated and mutually reinforcing. As a new form of industrial agglomeration, virtual agglomeration also helps to promote the diffusion of technology, which in turn promotes technological progress. The new generation of information technology makes the knowledge spillover of virtual agglomeration no longer rely on geographical proximity, reduces the cost of information collection, sharing costs, and expands the knowledge spillover effect [
13]. With technological support, information and data resources within virtual agglomerations are transmitted across virtual cyberspaces, which reduces the costs of negotiation and increase the frequency of communication through online interactions [
25], so that the new knowledge and technology can be transferred inside and outside the industry in a smarter and quicker way, which significantly enlarges the knowledge spillover and technology diffusion effect [
26].
The consensus is that knowledge spillovers and technology diffusion are generally considered less effective over greater distances, as they are influenced by geographical distance. However, virtual agglomeration, leveraging digital technology, create a “zero-distance” effect, reducing the spatial stickiness of knowledge spillover and exhibiting an “inverse distance decay” effect. Furthermore, through agglomeration platforms, technology diffusion can occur across multiple times and spaces, effectively reducing the latency of technology diffusion. Advanced technologies from developed regions can spread to less developed areas, fostering technical dividends through “learning by doing” and “imitative innovation-autonomous innovation” channels [
16], broadening the scope of technology diffusion.
Virtual agglomerations also reduce the spatial distance of technology diffusion, decreasing the likelihood of technology dormancy, and transition from a “one-to-one” to a “one-to-many” technology diffusion model [
16]. In practice, industrial cloud platforms represent typical types of virtual agglomerations, such as “Huawei Cloud”, “Xu Gong Industrial Cloud”,and “Haier Cloud”. These platforms host a mix of large advanced manufacturing enterprises and small and medium-sized enterprises with weaker digital capabilities. Large manufacturing companies, with stronger technology R&D orientation, R&D personnel, and R&D strength, can radiate their research results to smaller enterprises on the platform. Secondly, cloud platforms act as “intermediaries”, publishing technical requirements and bottlenecks, which can be solved on the platform.
The above analyses show that virtual agglomeration can realise the agglomeration effect of multi-party linkage, improve quality and efficiency, and promote technological progress.
2.3. Virtual Agglomeration Can Further Expand Economies of Scale
Marshall posited that the basis of industrial agglomeration lies in externalities, and identified the development of specialized inputs and services, the formation of a labor pool, and knowledge spillovers as pivotal drivers of such clustering. He further argued that a higher concentration of firms within the same industry in a particular area enhances the aggregation of production factors, leading to pronounced economies of scale and scope. However, Hoover introduced the concept of optimal agglomeration size, suggesting that surpassing a region’s maximum carrying capacity results in negative externalities such as elevated housing costs, increased pollution, and congestion effects. These contribute to a threshold in agglomeration size, depicted by an inverted U-shaped efficiency curve of industrial agglomeration, which restricts the scale economies.
Virtual clustering, as a state of “aggregation without congestion”, where clustered entities are distributed across different regions, presents a decentralized organizational structure and a boundless spatial layout. This effectively avoids congestion effects and overcomes geographical limitations. The scale of virtual clusters is not affected by environmental carrying capacities, thus breaking through the “optimal scale theory” and exhibiting a trend of increasing returns to scale.
In 1991, Krugman classified the sources of Marshall’s external scale economies into three categories: (1) Labour market Pooling; (2) Intermediate Input Sharing; and (3) Knowledge Spillovers. The development of virtual agglomeration expands the labour market pooling. Under virtual agglomeration, the employment landscape becomes more flexible, significantly reducing the necessity of geographical proximity to employers. This leads to a substantial decrease in the bilateral matching costs of labor demand and supply, potentially nearing zero [
14], and the agglomeration platform can also facilitate talent sharing. Secondly, virtual agglomeration can realize the sharing effects of intermediate inputs through various approaches such as digital platform construction, supply chain coordination, procurement and inventory optimization, informatization applications, and resource sharing. It can also instantly capture any amount of intermediate inputs available in the market, reducing the marginal acquisition costs of intermediate products [
16]. Thirdly, the spillover effects of virtual agglomeration are more pronounced, as discussed earlier with the knowledge spillover effects of virtual agglomeration. Additionally, virtual agglomeration platforms can achieve “co-investment, co-research, and co-sharing” effects. In virtual agglomeration, cooperation and communication between enterprises form an innovation network that promotes the sharing and diffusion of knowledge, providing more opportunities and support for corporate innovation activities. However, specialization is the fundamental driver of external economies of scale growth; industrial clusters themselves do not generate external economies of scale. Their essence lies in reducing the costs of specialization and cooperation, creating favorable conditions for microeconomic entities to utilize external economies of scale [
12]. Virtual agglomeration has relatively weak barriers, and the virtual transformation of clusters will further shorten the “distance” of specialization and cooperation, making nationwide specialization possible. Moreover, next-generation information technology reduces the information matching and selection costs for enterprises in virtual agglomeration. Leveraging the Internet, virtual agglomeration transitions from “real” to “virtual”, breaking through the closed nature of physical boundaries, facilitating efficient information transmission, and breaking down information barriers. Producers in virtual agglomeration can timely capture demand-side information on demand structure, quantity, and quality, making production and service decisions based on consumer needs, achieving demand-supply balance without the risk of product backlogs, and realizing economies of scale effects. In a sense, virtual agglomeration possesses dual characteristics of “gathering demand” and “realizing supply” [
5].
The above theoretical relationships can be represented as
Figure 1.
The above analysis indicates that virtual agglomeration has a positive effect on all three sources contributing to the improvement of total factor productivity. Therefore, we state our first hypothesis:
Hypothesis 1. Virtual agglomeration plays an active role in total factor productivity.
2.4. The nonlinear Relationship between Virtual Agglomeration and Total Factor Productivity
The understanding of the development and impact of virtual agglomeration can draw on the ideas from “New Economic Geography,” particularly the views on agglomeration economies’ externalities by Paul Krugman. In Krugman’s theoretical framework, agglomeration economies’ externalities refer to the increased production efficiency and cost benefits that arise when firms and labor are geographically concentrated.
There have been plenty of empirical studies that have analyzed the influence of spatial agglomeration on industrial or regional productivity and most conclude that a positive relationship exists [
27,
28]. Industrial agglomeration is conducive to reduce the production cost of enterprises [
29]. However, industrial agglomeration will also bring about “crowding effect” [
30]. Positive externalities of agglomeration are mainly spillover effects, including knowledge spillover and technology spillover. But technology spillover was local, decreased as geographical distance increased and decreased by half at about 1200 km [
31].
Generally, from a micro perspective, firms with certain production capacity can only focus on domestic or international markets [
32] . As two different forms of markets, virtual agglomeration and geographic agglomeration also have a substitution relationship, and the development of virtual agglomeration will inevitably crowd out geographic agglomeration, which in turn affects the spillover effect of knowledge and technology. Although no scholars have yet suggested that the development of virtual agglomeration on too large a scale will inhibit total factor productivity, economic intuition tells us that virtual agglomeration cannot expand indefinitely to replace traditional agglomeration. It must have boundaries. Only at a reasonable level can virtual agglomeration contribute positively to total factor productivity. Based on the aforementioned analysis, we advance the following hypotheses:
Hypothesis 2
. There is a U-shaped relationship between VA and TFP. Specifically, VA has a positive impact on TFP at first, but tends to be negative when the level of VA is high.
5. Conclusion and Policy
5.1. Conclusion
As digital technology continues to evolve, the phenomenon of virtual agglomeration is becoming increasingly common, with typical patterns such as virtual agglomeration in the service and manufacturing industries gaining significant attention from both the academic and industrial communities. Based on panel data from 30 provinces in Mainland China from 2013 to 2021, comprehensive measurement indices for virtual agglomeration were constructed from four aspects: infrastructure, output, input, and services of virtual agglomeration. The relationship between virtual agglomeration and total factor productivity was also analyzed and calculated. The main conclusions are as follows:
Firstly, overall, the level of virtual agglomeration in Mainland China is at a low development stage, and there is a considerable gap from the optimal level of virtual agglomeration. Secondly, virtual agglomeration can significantly enhance regional total factor productivity, but it shows a negative marginal effect in an inverted U-shaped relationship, i.e., as virtual agglomeration increases, total factor productivity decreases after reaching its peak value. Thirdly, the effect of virtual agglomeration on total factor productivity shows economic belt heterogeneity. Provinces in the Yangtze River Economic Belt see a greater enhancement effect on total factor productivity from virtual agglomeration, but provinces outside the Yangtze River Economic Belt have higher optimal levels of virtual agglomeration. Fourthly, the promoting effect of virtual agglomeration on total factor productivity exhibits regional heterogeneity. The optimal level of virtual agglomeration in western provinces is significantly higher than that in central and eastern provinces, with the central region having the highest total factor productivity at the optimal level of virtual agglomeration.
These results confirm the complex relationship between virtual agglomeration and total factor productivity, which is an important finding in responding to the global market environment and has significant policy implications for regional industrial development. The main contribution of this paper is to empirically and theoretically confirm the nonlinear relationship and regional heterogeneity in the impact of virtual agglomeration on total factor productivity. Additionally, there is room for improvement in the study, primarily due to the availability of data. The evaluation index system for the development level of virtual agglomeration is not comprehensive enough, which may lead to biases in the measurement results. In future research, the measurement of virtual agglomeration can be refined, and a more comprehensive index system for the development level of virtual agglomeration can be constructed. Furthermore, with newly released data, the time span of the panel data can be extended for more in-depth studies.
5.2. Policy
The policy implication contained are as follows: First, considering that the problem of insufficient development levels of virtual agglomeration, to unleash the total factor productivity effects of virtual agglomeration, it is necessary to establish a long-term mechanism to ensure ensure the coherence and continuity of virtual agglomeration development and to promote the coordinated linkage of virtual agglomeration development in different regions.
Second, The development of virtual agglomeration could significantly contribute to an increase in total factor productivity. Therefore, we should should give full play to the role of virtual agglomeration in promoting total factor productivity. We should accelerate the use of big data, cloud computing, artificial intelligence, and other digital technologies to promote the development of virtual agglomeration, and vigorously build industrial internet platforms and service internet platforms. However, as the virtual agglomeration effect has a threshold, it is necessary to pay attention to the reasonable space of the virtual agglomeration economy while vigorously developing it.
Third, based on the regional heterogeneity of the relationship between virtual agglomeration and total factor productivity, emphasis should be placed on comprehensive consideration and regional coordination. The central and western regions should focus on improving the application of digital technologies and the level of virtual agglomeration by increasing the construction of new infrastructure, improving transportation networks, and providing fiscal subsidies. Actively explore virtual radiation pathways and security mechanisms in the eastern region to empower the development of the central and western regions with digital technology. Enhance the cross-regional mobility of resource elements in the eastern, central, and western regions, and through a co-construction and sharing model, drive inter-regional industrial collaboration, address the resource shortages in the central and western regions, and unleash the Metcalfe’s multiplier effect of regional cooperation.
Fourth, considering the optimal level of virtual agglomeration, it is essential to explore new paths of “virtual-real overlay” cluster development to promote the integration of virtual and physical industries. While virtual agglomeration is rapidly developing, it is necessary to guard against the risk of shifting from tangible to intangible and to explore the dynamic balance between virtual agglomeration and geographic agglomeration. The externalities of geographic agglomeration are undeniable and constitute an important pattern in China’s industrial layout and development. While promoting virtual agglomeration, the fundamental role of geographic agglomeration should not be overlooked. Using geographic agglomeration as a lever, push for the platformization of industries, online modularization, networked connections, and intelligent production. Develop rules for virtual agglomeration to lower the entry barriers to platforms; provide specialized training in virtual agglomeration to enhance the virtual agglomeration capacity of industrial entities; and formulate support policies for virtual agglomeration to reduce market risks associated with virtual agglomeration.