Preprint
Article

Distortion Risk Measures of Increasing Rearrangements

Altmetrics

Downloads

88

Views

34

Comments

0

A peer-reviewed article of this preprint also exists.

This version is not peer-reviewed

Submitted:

16 August 2024

Posted:

19 August 2024

You are already at the latest version

Alerts
Abstract
The increasing rearrangement is a rewarding instrument in financial risk management. In practice, risk must be managed in different perspectives. A common example is portfolio risk which often can be seen from at least two perspectives: market value and book value. Different perspectives that is different distributions can be coupled by increasing rearrangement. One distribution is regarded as underlying, and the other distribution can be expressed as increasing rearrangement of the underlying distribution. Then, the risk measure for the latter can be expressed in terms of the underlying distribution. Our first objective is to introduce the increasing rearrangement for application in financial risk management and apply the increasing rearrangement to the class of distortion risk measures. We derive formulas to compute risk measures in terms of the underlying distribution. Afterwards, we apply our results to a series of special distortion risk measures, namely Value at Risk, Expected Shortfall, Range Value at Risk, Conditional Value at Risk, Wang's risk measure. Finally, we present the connection of increasing rearrangement to inverse transform sampling, Monte Carlo simulation, and cost-efficient strategies. Butterfly options serve as illustrative example for the method.
Keywords: 
Subject: Business, Economics and Management  -   Finance

MSC:  62P05; 62P20; 91B05; 91G70

1. Introduction

Increasing rearrangements often appear in finance and risk management in a natural context. For example, consider the market value and book value of a portfolio, where the book value is reported according to some reporting standard. In many cases, the portfolio risk has to be managed based on market values as well as book values – both points of view may be important and there may be even more perspectives to be controlled. Mostly, the book value can be regarded as an increasing function of the market value. In this case, risk measures of book and market values are related in a special manner. Given that the distribution of the market values does not have atoms, distortion risk measures of book values can be written in terms of the corresponding market values. This gives insight and computational advance.
The class of distortion risk measures to which this idea applies is a rather general yet useful and handy class of risk measures. All distortion risk measures are coherent as defined by Artzner et al. [1], i.e. they are translation invariant, monotonous, sub-additive, and positively homogeneous. Distortion risk measures were introduced by Denneberg [8] and Wang [20]. Their roots lie in the dual utility theory of Yaari [21], where it is shown that there must exist a type of function such that a prospect is valued at its distorted expectation. In place of using the tail probabilities in order to quantify risk, the decision maker uses the distorted tail probabilities. A general overview of distortion risk measures and their relation with the orderings of risks and the concept of comonotonicity can be found in [6] and [7].
Distortion risk measures allow an asset manager to reflect a client’s attitude towards risk by choosing the appropriate distortion function. For instance, in insurance data analytics and actuarial practice, distortion risk measures are used to capture the riskiness of the distribution tail and then employed to price extreme events, to develop reserves, to design risk transfer strategies, and to allocate capital.
The example of book and market values generalizes to any two distributions when one of them does not have atoms, as in this case an increasing rearrangement exists that transforms the continuous distribution into the other. Hence, given any distribution, we may find the increasing rearrangement with respect to some continuous distribution of our choice (e.g. uniform or normal distribution) and compute the risk of the given distribution in terms of the continuous distribution we chose.
Inverse transform sampling is a special case of this setting. In this case, the continuous distribution is the uniform distribution on [ 0 , 1 ] . Monte Carlo methods often use inverse transform sampling. Another example are cost-efficient portfolios as it turns out that the increasing and decreasing rearrangement yields explicit formulas for cost-efficient (and cost-inefficient) portfolios.
The article is organized as follows:
In Section 2 we introduce the increasing rearrangement in two versions called the “quantile version” and the “transport version”. While the quantile version is especially advantageous in finance – as it has the transformation property needed when applied to risk measures – the transport version is a little smoother in a way and for this reason preferred when applied to optimal transport, hence our naming.
The following Section 3 brings the application of increasing rearrangements (quantile version) to distortion risk measures. We derive formulas of how to compute the risk in terms of the underlying continuous distribution (“market values”).
This can be applied in Section 4 to a series of special distortion risk measures, namely Value at Risk, Expected Shortfall, Range Value at Risk, Conditional Value at Risk, and Wang’s risk measure.
We apply increasing rearrangement to inverse transform sampling and Monte Carlo simulation in Section 5. An example is the butterfly spread with R code provided in Appendix A. Finally, we point out the relation of increasing rearrangement to the theory of cost-efficient strategies.

2. The Increasing Rearrangement

The increasing rearrangement is related to the generalized inverse of distribution functions. Therefore we first introduce this concept. Here and in the following, increasing means
f ( a ) f ( b ) for all a b in the range of definition of   f .
Definition 2.1. 
Let T : R R be an increasing function. The generalized inverse T of T is defined by
T ( y ) : = inf x R | T ( x ) y ,
with inf = .
Let F be any distribution function. For α ( 0 , 1 ) , we denote the corresponding quantile function with q α ( F ) . It coincides with the generalized inverse F ( α ) and is given by
q α ( F ) = F ( α ) = inf x R | F ( x ) α .
If X is a random variable with distribution function F, we write q α ( X ) q α ( F ) as well. To specify distribution functions, we write F X for the distribution function of X. If X and Y have the same distribution function, we write X = d Y . If X has distribution F X , we write X F X .
We assume all random variables to be elements of some domain X L 0 of random variables with values in R { } and X be a convex cone, i.e. α X + β Y X for all X , Y X and α , β > 0 .
Given any increasing function T : R R , the generalized inverse T of T is increasing and left-continuous (cf. [14], p. 641 f.).
Proposition 2.2. [14], p. 642 If X is a random variable with distribution function F X and g : R R is increasing and left-continuous, then
F g X ( α ) = g F X ( α ) for all   α ( 0 , 1 ) .
In terms of the quantile function, this means
q α ( g X ) = g q α ( X ) for all   α ( 0 , 1 ) .
Definition 2.3. 
Let T : R R be an increasing function. The right-continuous generalized inverse T of T is defined by
T ( y ) : = inf x R | T ( x ) > y ,
with inf = .
Definition 2.4. 
Let X and Y be random variables with distribution functions F X and F Y . The increasing rearrangement (quantile version) of Y with respect to X is given by
g : = F Y F X .
The increasing rearrangement (transport version) of Y with respect to X is given by
g : = F Y F X .
Lemma 2.5. [18], p. 19 f. Let X and Y be random variables. Let g be the increasing rearrangement (transport version) of Y with respect to X. Then the following holds:
1. 
g is increasing.
2. 
g is right-continuous.
3. 
If X does not have atoms, then Y = d g ( X ) .
Lemma 2.6. 
Let X and Y be random variables. Let g be the increasing rearrangement (quantile version) of Y with respect to X. Then the following holds:
1. 
g is increasing.
2. 
If X does not have atoms, then g is left-continuous.
3. 
If X does not have atoms, then Y = d g ( X ) .
Proof. (i) The functions F X and F Y are increasing, and so is g .
(ii) X does not have atoms iff F X is continuous. Moreover, F Y is left-continuous. This implies (2).
(iii) The continuity of F X implies F X ( X ) U [ 0 , 1 ] (uniformly distributed on [ 0 , 1 ] ). Hence F Y F X ( X ) = d Y . (cf. [10], p. 429)    □
While the quantile version of the increasing rearrangement seems to be a natural choice in terms of the generalized inverse and favorable in view of Proposition 2.2, the transport version of the increasing rearrangement is right-continuous without further assumptions on X. Villani praises the transport version of the increasing rearrangement: “This rearrangement is quite simple, explicit, as smooth as can be, and enjoys good geometric properties” [18], p. 20.

3. Risk measures of increasing rearrangements

Distortion risk measures are law-invariant risk measures and include Value at Risk and Expected Shortfall. They are defined in the following way:
Definition 3.1. [17]
1.
A distortion function D is an increasing, right-continuous function on [ 0 , 1 ] satisfying D ( 0 ) = 0 and D ( 1 ) = 1 .
2.
The distortion risk measure associated with a distortion function D is defined by
ϱ D ( X ) : = 0 1 q u ( X ) d D ( u ) .
Note that in our notation we regard X as loss function, i.e. positive values of X stand for losses, negative values of X stand for profits. If one uses a p&l-function with an opposite interpretation, the formulas here and in the following have to be altered accordingly.
In [14] the definition of distortion risk measures is given for the smaller class of convex, absolutely continuous distortion functions. With respect to these distortion functions, the corresponding distortion risk measures are coherent. However, this excludes Value at Risk from the class, which is why we prefer the more general Definition 3.1 of Tsukahara.
Let D be an absolutely continuous distortion function and φ be the right derivative of D. Then φ is a non-negative function, and
D ( u ) = 0 u φ ( s ) d s .
One defines
Definition 3.2. 
Let φ be the right derivative of an absolutely continuous distortion function. The spectral risk measure with respect to φ is
ϱ φ ( X ) : = 0 1 q u ( X ) φ ( u ) d u .
One calls φ the spectrum of ϱ φ .
If φ is the right derivative of an absolutely continuous distortion function D, then ϱ D = ϱ φ holds by construction.
Lemma 3.3. 
Let D be a distortion function and ϱ D the risk measure associated with D. Then ϱ D can be written in the form
ϱ D ( X ) = x d D F X ( x ) .
Proof. 
The proof given in [14], p. 287 for convex and absolutely continuous distortion function D applies literally.    □
The chain rule, applied to (12), implies
Lemma 3.4. 
Let D be an absolutely continuous distortion function, φ its spectrum and ϱ φ the risk measure associated with φ. Let X be a random variable with an absolutely continuous distribution function F X and let f X be the right-derivative of F X (density of X). Then ϱ φ can be written in the form
ϱ φ ( X ) = x φ F X ( x ) f X ( x ) d x .
Theorem 3.5. 
Let X and Y be random variables and X be atomless. Let g be the quantile version of increasing rearrangement of Y with respect to X. Let D be a distortion function and ϱ D the distortion risk measure associated with D. Then the following holds:
ϱ D ( Y ) = 0 1 q u ( Y ) d D ( u ) = 0 1 g q u ( X ) d D ( u ) ,
ϱ D ( Y ) = x d D F Y ( x ) = g ( x ) d D F X ( x ) .
If D is absolutely continuous and φ is the corresponding spectrum, we have
ϱ φ ( Y ) = 0 1 q u ( Y ) φ ( u ) d u = 0 1 g q u ( X ) φ ( u ) d u .
Moreover, if X is absolutely continuous with density f X ,
ϱ φ ( Y ) = g ( x ) φ F X ( x ) f X ( x ) d x .
Note that representation (17) cannot be written down in terms of F Y , because F Y is not supposed to be absolutely continuous (not even continuous).
Proof. 
By Lemma 5.3., g is an increasing, left-continuous function, and Y = d g ( X ) . Thus Proposition 2.2 applies and yields (14) and (16).
To show (15), we write G ( x ) = D F X ( x ) and observe G ( x ) = F X D ( x ) .1 Now
g ( x ) d G ( x ) = 0 1 g G ( u ) d u = 0 1 g F X D ( u ) d u = E g F X D ( U ) , U U [ 0 , 1 ] .
We introduce the random variable V = D ( U ) and obtain with (14)
g ( x ) d D F X ( x ) = E g F X ( V ) = 0 1 g F X ( v ) d D ( v ) = ϱ D ( Y ) .
This shows (15). Finally, applying the chain rule to (15) implies (17) and this finishes the proof.    □

4. Application to Special Risk Measures

4.1. Application to Value at Risk

Value at Risk of a loss distribution is defined to be the quantile at some confidence level α ( 0 , 1 ) , we write
VaR α ( Y ) : = q α ( Y ) .
Value at Risk is a distortion risk measure with distortion function
D ( u ) = 1 [ α , 1 ] ( u ) .
(See [17] for more details.) Hence, Theorem 3.5 applied to VaR yields the well-known
Lemma 4.1. 
Let X and Y be random variables and X does not have atoms. Let g be the quantile version of increasing rearrangement of Y with respect to X. Then
VaR α ( Y ) = g VaR α ( X ) .
Proof. 
The assertion follows from equation (14) of Theorem 3.5. Also, it is a consequence of Lemma 5.3. (iii) in combination with Proposition 2.2, namely:
VaR α ( Y ) = F Y ( α ) = F g X ( α ) = g F X ( α ) = g VaR α ( X ) .
   □

4.2. Application to Expected Shortfall

The Expected Shortfall of a random variable Y with E ( Y + ) < and confidence level α ( 0 , 1 ) , e.g. α = 0.995 , is the spectral risk measure defined as follows:
ES α ( Y ) : = 0 1 q u ( Y ) φ ES ( u ) d u
with specific spectrum
φ ES ( u ) : = 1 1 α 1 [ α , 1 ) ( u ) for   u [ 0 , 1 ] .
Alternatively, Expected Shortfall can be represented in terms of the distortion function of the form:
D ES ( u ) = α u φ ES ( s ) d s = max u α 1 α , 0 , u [ 0 , 1 ] ,
(This follows from Definition 3.2 of distortion risk measures.) For continuous random variables X, Expected Shortfall has an intuitive interpretation as conditional expectation, namely
ES α ( X ) = E X | X q α ( X ) .
For discontinous random variables though, one has to be careful and the proper definition in this general case amounts to [14], p. 283
ES α ( X ) = 1 1 α E X 1 ( q α ( X ) , ) ( X ) + q α ( X ) 1 α P ( X > q α ( X ) ) .
Nevertheless, the theorem on increasing rearrangement and distortion risk measures allows to find a version of formula (27) for discontinuous random variables as follows:
Theorem 4.2. 
Let X and Y be random variables and X be absolutely continuous. Let g be the quantile version of increasing rearrangement of Y with respect to X. Let E ( Y + ) < . Then
ES α ( Y ) = E g ( X ) | X q α ( X ) .
Proof. 
As X is absolutely continuous there exists a density function f X . Consequently, the expected shortfall can be written in the form of equation (17) with the spectrum φ ES . We derive
ES α ( Y ) = g ( x ) φ ES F X ( x ) f X ( x ) d x = 1 1 α g ( x ) 1 [ α , 1 ) F X ( x ) f X ( x ) d x = 1 1 α g ( x ) 1 [ q α ( X ) , ) ( x ) f X ( x ) d x = 1 1 α E g ( X ) 1 [ q α ( X ) , ) ( X ) = E g ( X ) | X q α ( X )
as was to be shown.    □
In case Y = g ( X ) , X-a.s., Theorem 4.2. takes the striking form
ES α ( Y ) = E Y | X q α ( X ) .
The following theorem shows that this holds for any (not necessarily left-continuous) increasing transformation g with Y = g X , X-a.s., as well.
Theorem 4.3. 
Let X be an absolutely continuous random variable, and Y = g X , X-a.s., where g is increasing. Let E ( Y + ) < . Then
ES α ( Y ) = E ( Y | X q α ( X ) ) .
Proof. 
We consider the sets
Y x R | g ( x ) q α ( Y )   and   X x R | x q α ( X ) .
In the first place, X Y , or, what is the same,
1 Y 1 X 0 .
Indeed, for an arbitrary x X we obtain
α P ( X x ) P ( g ( X ) g ( x ) ) = P ( Y g ( x ) ) ,
which means x Y . This implies (34). Moreover, we find that
1 Y ( x ) 1 X ( x ) > 0   implies   g ( x ) = q α ( Y ) .
This can be shown by contradiction. Indeed, let x Y X be arbitrary and assume g ( x ) > q α ( Y ) . Then we obtain by the monotony of g and the absolute continuity of X
P ( X x ) = P ( X < x ) P ( g ( X ) < g ( x ) ) = P ( Y < g ( x ) ) P Y q α ( Y ) + g ( x ) q α ( Y ) 2 α ,
hence x q α ( X ) in contradiction to x X . Thus statement (36) holds.
Now we prove the theorem by showing
( 1 α ) ES α ( Y ) E ( g X | X q α ( X ) ) = 0 .
Representation (28) of Expected Shortfall is equivalent to
ES α ( Y ) = 1 1 α E Y 1 Y q α ( Y ) + q α ( Y ) 1 α P ( Y q α ( Y ) ,
as follows from
E Y 1 Y > q α ( Y ) = E Y 1 Y q α ( Y ) q α ( Y ) P ( Y = q α ( Y ) ) .
The random variable X is assumed to be absolutely continuous and hence possesses a probability density function f X . We calculate with (39)
( 1 α ) ES α ( Y ) E ( g X | X q α ( X ) ) = = E Y | Y q α ( Y ) + q α ( Y ) 1 α P ( Y q α ( Y ) ( 1 α ) E ( g X | X q α ( X ) ) = g ( x ) 1 Y ( x ) f X ( x ) d x + q α ( Y ) 1 X ( x ) f X ( x ) d x q α ( Y ) 1 Y ( x ) f X ( x ) d x g ( x ) 1 X ( x ) f X ( x ) d x = g ( x ) q α ( Y ) 1 Y ( x ) 1 X ( x ) f X ( x ) d x .
By (34) an (36), the integrand vanishes. This shows (38) and thus the theorem is proven.    □

4.3. Application to Range-Value-at-Risk

Next, we highlight Range-Value-at-Risk introduced by [4]. It is a modified version of Expected Shortfall such that an average of VaR levels is calculated across a pre-defined range of loss probabilities. Let 0 < α < 1 , 0 < β 1 α , then
RVaR α , β ( X ) : = 1 β α α + β VaR u ( X ) d u .
Range-Value-at-Risk has good statistical properties (“ C -robustness”) which carry over to Expected Shortfall in a certain sense as is discussed in [4]. In applying our main theorem 3.5, we derive a formula for the Range-Value-at-Risk of Y in terms of X:
Theorem 4.4. 
Let X and Y be random variables and X be absolutely continuous. Let g be the quantile version of increasing rearrangement of Y with respect to X. Let E ( Y + ) < and β > 0 , α + β 1 . Then
RVaR α , β ( Y ) = E g ( X ) | q α + β ( X ) X q α ( X ) .
Proof. 
The assumption of absolute continuity of X gives us the possibility to write the Range-Value-at-Risk in terms of the density function f X by (17), as follows:
RVaR α , β ( Y ) ) = 1 β α β + α VaR u ( Y ) d u = 1 β 0 1 1 ( α , α + β ) ( u ) q u ( Y ) d u = 1 β g ( x ) 1 ( α , α + β ) F X ( x ) f X ( x ) d x = 1 β g ( x ) 1 q α ( X ) , q α + β ( X ) x f X ( x ) d x = E g ( X ) | q α + β ( X ) X q α ( X ) ,
as was to be shown.    □

4.4. Application to Conditional Value at Risk

The distributional transform is defined as follows [3,15]: Let X be a real random variable with distribution function F and let V U ( 0 , 1 ) be uniformly distributed on ( 0 , 1 ) and independent of X. The modified distribution function  F ( x , λ ) is defined by
F ( x , λ ) : = P ( X < x ) + λ P ( X = x ) .
The (generalized) distributional transform of X is then defined by
U : = F ( X , V ) .
An equivalent representation of the distributional transform is
U = F ( X ) + V ( F ( X ) F ( X ) ) .
An early source for this transform is the statistics book [11]. See [16, p. 21-28] for a range of applications of the distributional transform. By means of the distributional transform one can give a proper definition of Conditional Value at Risk, namely (see [3], [15])
CVaR α ( X ) = E ( X | U α ) .
The main theorem on conditional value at risk is that it actually coincides with expected shortfall. We prove this result of Burgert and Rüschendorf by applying Theorem 4.2.
Corollary 4.5. 
[3] Let Y be a random variable and U its distributional transform. Let E ( Y + ) < . Then
ES α ( Y ) = E ( Y | U α ) .
Proof. 
For the distributional transform U of Y it holds that U U ( 0 , 1 ) and Y = F ( U ) a.s., see [15].
On [ 0 , 1 ] , F U is the identity. Hence the increasing rearrangement g of Y with respect to U equals F on [ 0 , 1 ] by (7). This implies Y = g ( U ) a.s.
U posesses a density (namely, the density of the uniform distribution on ( 0 , 1 ) ). That means that U is absolutely continuous and Theorem 4.2. applies. We obtain
ES α ( Y ) = E ( g ( U ) | U q α ( U ) ) .
Using Y = g ( U ) a.s., this implies
ES α ( Y ) = E ( Y | U q α ( U ) ) = CVaR α ( Y ) ,
as was to be shown.    □

4.5. Application to Wang’s risk measure

For the pricing of financial and insurance risk, [19] has introduced a specific distortion function which is based on the standard normal distribution Φ in combination with a shift parameter λ R :
D Wang , λ ( u ) = Φ Φ 1 ( x ) λ .
Formula (15) of Theorem 3.5 yields
Lemma 4.6. 
Let X and Y be random variables and X be normal distributed with μ R and σ 2 > 0 . Let g be the quantile version of increasing rearrangement of Y with respect to X. Let E ( Y + ) < . Then
ϱ Wang , λ ( Y ) = E g Z
holds for Z N ( μ + λ σ , σ 2 ) .
Likewise, let X be log-normal distributed with μ R and σ 2 > 0 and g be the quantile version of increasing rearrangement of Y with respect to X, E ( Y + ) < . Then (53) holds for log Z N ( μ + λ σ , σ 2 ) .
Proof. 
We start with the definition of Wang’s risk measure and (15):
ϱ Wang , λ ( Y ) = x d D Wang , λ F Y ( x ) = g ( x ) d D Wang , λ F X ( x ) .
Let us assume that X N ( μ , σ ) . We can equivalently write X in terms of the standard normal distribution, namely F X ( x ) = Φ x μ σ , and obtain for the integrator:
D Wang , λ F X ( x ) = Φ Φ 1 Φ x μ σ λ = Φ x μ σ λ σ .
This implies (53) with Z N μ + λ σ , σ 2 .
The analogous argument holds for log ( X ) N ( μ , σ ) and the log-normal distribution function F X ( x ) = Φ log ( x ) μ σ :
D Wang , λ F X ( x ) = Φ Φ 1 Φ log ( x ) μ σ λ = Φ log ( x ) μ σ λ σ .
Thus equation (53) holds in both cases and the Lemma is proven.    □
One may write the assertion of the lemma in terms of X rather than Z. Namely, in the notation of the lemma and in case X N ( μ , σ 2 ) , equation (53) amounts to
ϱ Wang , λ ( Y ) = E g ( X + λ σ ) .
In case log ( X ) N ( μ , σ 2 ) , (53) amounts to
ϱ Wang , λ ( Y ) = E g ( e σ λ X ) .

5. Application to Numerical Simulation and Cost-Efficient Portfolios

5.1. Inverse Transform Sampling

Inverse transform sampling is related to the increasing rearrangement. The well-known inversion principle (or, inversion method) to random number generation reads:
Theorem 5.1. 
Let F be a cumulative distribution function and X be uniformly distributed on ( 0 , 1 ) . Then Y : = F ( X ) has cdf F.
Proof. 
See e.g. [13], p. 87.    □
In this setting, the increasing rearrangement of Y with respect to X is
g ( X ) = F Y F X ( X ) = F Y ( X ) a . s .
In other words, F ( X ) as given in the theorem is the increasing rearrangement applied to X in special case X U ( 0 , 1 ) . Hence, all assertions of the preceding section apply to inverse transform sampling.

5.2. Monte Carlo simulation

In general, with Monte Carlo simulation, simulated prices are not an increasing rearrangement of random numbers or underlying prices, respectively. Consider for example a butterfly spread [12], p. 190 ff. with payoff as displayed in Table 1. Notation:
  • S T price of underlying at maturity T,
  • K 1 , K 2 , K 3 strike prices, K 1 < K 3 , K 2 = ( K 1 + K 3 ) / 2 .
The payoff of the butterfly spread reads as follows:
Table 1. payoff of butterfly spread.
Table 1. payoff of butterfly spread.
stock price payoff
S T < K 1 0
K 1 S T < K 2 S T K 1
K 2 S T < K 3 K 3 S T
K 3 S T 0
The payoff is depicted in Figure 1 (blue line). Given the model for stock prices, the distribution of the butterfly payoff can be obtained by the increasing rearrangement. Let us denote the butterfly payoff with Y = Y ( S T ) and the increasing rearrangement of Y with respect to S T by g . Then by Lemma 5.3 we have:
Y = d g ( S T ) .
This is easy to compute in the Monte Carlo simulation. One just has to sort Y. R code is provided in the appendix.
Assuming a lognormal distribution for S T with μ = 0 , σ = 20 % and T = 1 / 52 , we obtain Figure 1. The payoff Y is denoted with the blue line, g ( S T ) with the red line. Note that g ( S T ) is increasing while Y is not. However, both have the same distribution.

5.3. Cost-Efficient Strategies

A strategy (or a payoff) is said to be cost-efficient if any other strategy that generates the same distribution costs at least as much. Starting with Cox and Leland [5], Dybvig [9] pointed out that there are indeed inefficient strategies in the market. Examples like the so-called constant proportion portfolio insurance (CPPI), or the butterfly spread discussed in section 5.2 show, as Dybvig puts it, “how to throw away a million dollars in the stock market”.
It turns out that a payoff is cost-efficient if and only if it is non-increasing in the state-price almost surely, see [2] for an introduction into the topic, proofs and references. We will make this statement more explicit in Theorem 5.4 below.
In the words of Bernard et al.: “The cheapest way to achieve a lottery assigns outcomes of the lottery to the states in reverse order of the state-price density.” [2] So we define the decreasing rearrangement, as follows:
Definition 5.2. 
Let X and Y be random variables with distribution functions F X and F Y . The decreasing rearrangement (quantile version) of Y with respect to X is given by
g ˜ : = F Y ( 1 F X ) .
Lemma 5.3. 
Let X and Y be random variables. Let  g ˜  be the decreasing rearrangement (quantile version) of Y with respect to X. Then the following holds:
1. 
g ˜ is decreasing.
2. 
If X does not have atoms, then g ˜ is left-continuous.
3. 
If X does not have atoms, then Y = d g ˜ ( X ) .
Proof. (i) The function ( 1 F X ) is decreasing while F Y is increasing, so g ˜ is a decreasing function.
(ii) X does not have atoms iff F X is continuous. Moreover, F Y is left-continuous. This implies (2).
(iii) The continuity of F X implies F X ( X ) U [ 0 , 1 ] (uniformly distributed on [ 0 , 1 ] ), so 1 F X ( X ) U [ 0 , 1 ] as well. Hence F Y 1 F X ( X ) = d Y (cf. [10, p.429]).    □
We consider an arbitrage-free and complete market with an unique state-price density ξ t , t 0 and assume that ξ t is atomless for all t > 0 . In such a market the price (or cost) of a strategy (or of a financial investment contract) with terminal payoff X T at T > 0 is given by
c ( X T ) = E ξ T X T ,
where the expectation is taken under the physical measure. The Theorem on cost efficient strategies reads as follows.
Theorem 5.4. 
[2] Let X T be a given payoff, i.e. any random variable. Let ξ t , t 0 be the state-price density and g ˜ T the decreasing rearrangement (quantile version) of X T with respect to ξ T . Then g ˜ T = d X T and g ˜ T is thecost-efficientstrategy to replicate X T : Given any other random variable Y T with Y T = d X T , it holds that
c ( g ˜ T ) c ( Y T ) .
In the Black-Scholes model with positive expected return μ > 0 , stock prices and state prices at T > 0 are non-increasing functions of each other. Hence Theorem 5.4 amounts to the payoff be increasing in the stock price, i.e. the increasing rearrangement of the payoff in terms of the price of the underlying stock yields the cost-efficient strategy that replicates the distribution of the payoff under consideration. An example is given by the butterfly spread discussed in the previous section. While the given payoff is not cost-efficient, its increasing rearrangement is.
Note that the assertion hinges (amongst the other assumptions) on the assumption that μ > 0 . Investors who do not believe that the drift of stock is positive will consequently not conclude that the payoff of the increasing rearrangement of the butterfly spread is cost-efficient.

6. Conclusions

We consider distortion risk measures of increasing rearrangements. The “pull through property” of the increasing rearrangement with respect to quantiles implies formulas for the risk measure of Y in terms of X, given that Y is the increasing rearrangement of X.
The special case of Value at Risk illustrates the principle by the well-known formula
VaR α ( Y ) = g VaR α ( X ) ,
where Y = g X and g is the increasing rearrangement.
Moreover, applied to Expected Shortfall, the principle allows to generalize the interpretation of Expected Shortfall as conditional expectation. Namely, let Y be an arbitrary random variable (“book values”), X be an arbitrary absolutely continuous random variable (“market values”) and g be the increasing rearrangement of Y with respect to X. Then the Expected Shortfall of Y can be written as a conditional expectation on g X (which has the same distribution as Y) in terms of X. This applies to Range Value at Risk as well.
Next, the principle implies a Theorem of Burgert and Rüschendorf stating that Expected Shortfall equals Conditional Value at Risk. An application to Wang’s risk measure yields a representation of Wang’s risk measure as some expected value.
Finally, we highlight the connection of the principle to inverse transform sampling, Monte Carlo simulation, and cost-efficient strategies.

Acknowledgments

We thank Michael Diether, Gregor Fels, Dieter Kadelka, Julia Mehlitz, Thomas Plehn and Bruce Auchinleck for valuable discussions.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A R-code (butterfly example)

Figure 1 was drawn with the following R code:
N <- 100000
alpha <- 0.10 # conficence level 1 - alpha
sigma <- 0.2  # volatility
T <- 1 / 52 # time (week)
K1 <- 0.95
K3 <- 1.05
K2 <- (K1 + K3)  / 2
 
X <- sort(rlnorm(N, sdlog = sigma * sqrt(T)))
Y <- pmax(X - K1, 0) + pmax(X - K3, 0) - 2 * pmax(X - K2, 0)
 
plot(X, Y, type = "l", col = "blue", xlab = "price of underlying",
     ylab = "payoff")
     # main ="numerical increasing rearrangement of butterfly"
lines(X, sort(Y), type = "l", col = "red")
In the last line, the increasing rearrangement is done by just sorting Y.

References

  1. Artzner, Philippe; Delbaen, Freddy; Eber, Jean-Marc; Heath, David. Coherent measures of risk. Mathematical finance 1999, 9.3, 203-228. [CrossRef]
  2. Bernard, Carole; Boyle, Phelim P.; Vanduffel, Steven. Explicit representation of cost-efficient strategies. Finance 2014, 35.2, 5-55. [CrossRef]
  3. Burgert, Christian; Rüschendorf, Ludger. On the optimal risk allocation problem. Statistics and Decisions—International Journal Stochastic Methods and Models 2006, 24.1, 153-172. [CrossRef]
  4. Cont, Rama; Deguest, Romain; Scandolo, Giacomo. Robustness and sensitivity analysis of risk measurement procedures. Quantitative Finance 2010, 10.6, 593-606. [CrossRef]
  5. Cox, J.C.; Leland, H. On Dynamic Investment Strategies. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 2000, 24.11-12, 1859-1880.
  6. Denuit, Michel; Dhaene, Jan; Goovaerts, Marc; Kaas, Rob. Actuarial theory for dependent risks: measures, orders and models. John Wiley: Chichester, 2005.
  7. Dhaene, Jan; Vanduffel, Steven; Tang, Qihe; Goovaerts, Marc J.; Kaas, Rob ; Vyncke, David. Risk measures and comonotonicity: a review. Stochastic Models 2006, 22, 573606. [CrossRef]
  8. Denneberg, Dieter. Distorted probabilities and insurance premiums. Methods of Operations Research 1990, 63, 3-5.
  9. Dybvig, Phillip H. Inefficient dynamic portfolio strategies or how to throw away a million dollars in the stock market. The Review of Financial Studies 1988, 1.1, 67-88. [CrossRef]
  10. Embrechts, Paul; Hofert, Marius. A note on generalized inverses. Mathematical Methods of Operations Research 2013, 77.3, 423-432. [CrossRef]
  11. Ferguson, Thomas S. Probability and mathematical statistics. Academic Press: 1967.
  12. Hull, John. Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives. Prentice Hall: 5th ed. 2003.
  13. Kolonko, Michael. Stochastische Simulation. Vieweg+Teubner:2008.
  14. McNeil, Alexander J.; Frey, Rüdiger; Embrechts, Paul. Quantitative risk management: concepts, techniques and tools—revised edition. Princeton university press: 2015.
  15. Rüschendorf, Ludger. On the distributional transform, Sklar’s theorem, and the empirical copula process. Journal of Statistical Planning and Inference 2009, 139.11, 3921-3927. [CrossRef]
  16. Rüschendorf, Ludger. Mathematical risk analysis. Springer: Heidelberg, 2013.
  17. Tsukahara, Hideatsu. One-Parameter Families of Distortion Risk Measures. Mathematical Finance 2009, 19.4, 691-705. [CrossRef]
  18. Villani, Cedric. Optimal transport: old and new. Springer: 2008.
  19. Wang, Shaun S. A Class Of Distortion Operators For Pricing Financial And Insurance Risks. The Journal of Risk and Insurance 2000, 67.1, 15-36. [CrossRef]
  20. Wang, Shaun S.; Young, Virginia R.; Panjer, Harry H. Axiomatic characterization of insurance prices. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 1997, 21, 173-183. [CrossRef]
  21. Yaari, Menahem E. The dual theory of choice under risk. Econometrica 1987, 55, 95-116. [CrossRef]
1
Cf. [14], p. 287
Figure 1. Numerical increasing rearrangement of butterfly spread.
Figure 1. Numerical increasing rearrangement of butterfly spread.
Preprints 115453 g001
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.
Copyright: This open access article is published under a Creative Commons CC BY 4.0 license, which permit the free download, distribution, and reuse, provided that the author and preprint are cited in any reuse.
Prerpints.org logo

Preprints.org is a free preprint server supported by MDPI in Basel, Switzerland.

Subscribe

© 2024 MDPI (Basel, Switzerland) unless otherwise stated