4.1. Economic Benefit and Pollution Discharge
This study derives the Nash equilibrium solution and compromise programming solution for both players through the calculation of the CIMB-CP model. To facilitate comparative analysis, we employed the methodology proposed by lee [
14] to solve the Cost-Exclusive Multi-Objective Bargaining Methodology (CEMB) model and further applied compromise programming techniques for computational purposes. To quantitatively assess the differences between the two approaches, we plotted the results on a Pareto curve generated using the NSGA-II algorithm, thereby providing a visual representation of the decision discrepancies under the two methods. The outcomes for the Economic benefit and Pollution discharge in the middle and lower reaches of the Han River, obtained by different methods, are depicted in
Figure 4. In the CIMB-CP model, the discount factor for Player 1 and Player 2 are both set at 2, with the maximum number of bargaining rounds limited to 20.
By solving for the two players individually, we obtained the optimal solutions under single-objective conditions. We then substituted these solutions into the objective function of the other player to determine the bargaining ranges for both players. The results showed that Player 1’s bargaining range was (2525.0, 2894.7) billion yuan, and Player 2’s bargaining range was (629.77, 654.44) kiloton. The results calculated by the two methods are shown in
Figure 4(a). The Nash equilibrium solution obtained by CIMB were (2859.82 billion yuan, 635.64 kiloton) and (2820.81 billion yuan, 632.67 kiloton). Correspondingly, the equilibrium solution obtained by CEMB were (2858.40 billion yuan, 635.22 kiloton) and (2838.70 billion yuan, 633.24 kiloton). It is evident that the Nash equilibrium solution obtained through the Multi-Objective Bargaining Methodology (MOBM) significantly condensed the initial bargaining range. Moreover, compared to CEMB, the inclusion of negotiation cost further reduced the range of the Nash equilibrium solution in CIMB, indicating that the CIMB model holds greater practical value in real-world applications.
The distinct ranges of Nash equilibrium solution derived from the CIMB and CEMB methodologies inherently engender deviations in the final decision solution obtained through compromise programming. Specifically, the final decision solution for CEMB corresponds to an economic benefit of 2836.09 billion yuan, contrasted with the 2842.46 billion yuan associated with the final decision solution for CIMB. Concurrently, the pollution discharge magnitudes for these methods were 633.11 thousand tons and 633.35 thousand tons, respectively. Despite the marginal economic benefit enhancement when considering negotiation cost, this adjustment also resulted in a slight uptick in pollution discharge. By applying the max-min method, we calculated the utility point corresponding to the final decision solutions of the CEMB-CP and CIMB-CP method, yielding (0.8415, 0.8646) and (0.8587, 0.8549), respectively. Our analysis revealed that within the CIMB-CP model, the utility points for both players were more proximate, signifying that the negotiation process rendered the utilities more equilibrated. By integrating negotiation cost, decision-makers can more effectively discern and leverage interdependent interests, thereby fostering cooperative and coordinated strategies.
4.2. Water Resources Allocation
In the statistical calculation of water resource allocation in the middle and lower reaches of the Han River basin, we employed two models, CEMB-CP and CIMB-CP, yielding respective water resource allocation quantities of 13.67 billion cubic meters and 14.55 billion cubic meters. To gain a deeper understanding of the water resource allocation under these two models for each city, we conducted a detailed analysis of the water shortage volume and shortage ratio for each city and visualized the results in
Figure 5.
From the data in
Figure 5, it is evident that the results derived from the CEMB-CP model generally exhibit higher water shortages in both volume and ratio compared to the CIMB-CP model. Specifically, the CEMB-CP model indicates that Xiangyang has the highest water shortage volume at 0.78 billion cubic meters, followed by Xiaogan at 0.55 billion cubic meters. In stark contrast, Shennongjia shows the lowest water shortage volume at only 0.003 billion cubic meters. The results from the CIMB-CP model also exhibit a similar trend, with Xiangyang recording a water shortage volume of 0.73 billion cubic meters, followed closely by Xiaogan at 0.48 billion cubic meters. Shennongjia continues to exhibit the lowest water shortage volume at 0.002 billion cubic meters. In terms of water shortage ratio, the CEMB-CP model points out that Wuhan has the highest water shortage ratio at 27.44%, followed by Xiangyang at 23.19%. Although Jingmen has the lowest water shortage ratio, it still stands at a considerable 12.59%. The results from the CIMB-CP model differ slightly, with the highest water shortage ratio occurring in Xiangyang at 21.64%, while Wuhan's water shortage ratio is 19.95%. Again, Jingmen maintains the lowest water shortage ratio at 6.29%.
In summary, whether from the perspective of water resource shortage volume or ratio, Xiangyang and Xiaogan face relatively greater water resource pressure, while Shennongjia and Jingmen perform relatively better in these two indicators. These analyses provide crucial reference data for understanding the allocation and management of water resources in the middle and lower reaches of the Han River basin, laying a foundation for future water resource planning and policy formulation.
Based on the CEMB-CP and CIMB-CP models, we obtained the water allocation results for four water-use sectors (domestic, industrial, agricultural, and ecological) across various cities in the middle and lower reaches of the Han River. The specific data are presented in
Figure 6 and
Figure 7. Figures 6(a) and 7(a) illustrate the total water consumption and the proportion of each water-use sector in each city according to both models. It can be observed that Shennongjia has the smallest total allocated water amount, with both models providing a result of 0.01 billion cubic meters, while Jingmen has the largest total allocation, with values of 2.76 billion cubic meters and 2.96 billion cubic meters respectively. Overall, the order of total water resources distribution obtained from the two models is largely consistent, with the only exceptions being the adjusted order for Qianjiang and Wuhan between the two models.
It is evident from the figure that the domestic sector consistently accounts for the majority of total water usage across most cities, reflecting a high demand for water resources in daily urban life. However, cities like Qianjiang and Shennongjia exhibit relatively lower domestic water allocation proportions, which may be attributed to local water resource management strategies or residents' water usage habits.
In contrast to the domestic sector, the industrial sector's water allocation proportion is markedly lower. Cities such as Jingmen, Qianjiang, Tianmen, Xiantao, Xiaogan, and Nanyang have industrial water usage ratios below 15%, indicating that the industrial development in these regions has not yet reached a high water-consuming stage or that water-saving measures have been implemented. Only a few cities have a higher industrial water allocation proportion, such as Shennongjia, where the industrial sector's water allocation accounts for 43.90% and 39.13% under the CEMB-CP and CIMB-CP models, respectively.
The water allocation for the agricultural sector varies significantly across different cities. For example, Shennongjia and Shiyan have agricultural water usage ratios exceeding 30%, highlighting the agricultural sector's significant role locally. In other cities, the agricultural water usage proportion generally falls between 10% and 15%, indicating differing impacts of agricultural development across regions.
The ecological sector's water allocation proportion exhibits the most significant fluctuations among cities. For instance, Qianjiang, Tianmen, Xiangyang, and Nanyang have ecological water allocation ratios exceeding 11%. Among these, Tianmen has the highest ecological water usage, accounting for 27.34% and 32.43% under the CEMB-CP and CIMB-CP models, respectively. In contrast, cities like Shennongjia, Shiyan, and Xiangyang have ecological water allocation ratios below 5%.
In summary, the disparities in water resource allocation across different cities reflect varying economic structures, development stages, and environmental protection awareness. Effective water resource management is crucial not only for sustainable urban development but also for environmental protection. Policymakers should therefore pay attention to the differences in water usage proportions across sectors and implement scientific planning and distribution to enhance water resource utilization efficiency, thereby promoting coordinated economic and ecological development.
Based on the statistical results shown in
Figure 6(b) and
Figure 7(b), a comparison of water allocation between the CEMB-CP and CIMB-CP models across four sectors—domestic, industrial, agricultural, and ecological—reveals that domestic water usage constitutes the largest proportion in both models, accounting for 60% and 57%, respectively. Specifically, in the CEMB-CP model, the proportions for industrial, agricultural, and ecological water usage are 15%, 14%, and 11%, respectively. In contrast, under the CIMB-CP model, these proportions are 14%, 16%, and 13%, respectively. Although the allocation ratios for domestic and industrial water usage differ slightly between the two models, the total water allocation difference is minimal because the CIMB-CP model allocates a higher total volume of water. The additional water resources in the CIMB-CP model are primarily directed towards agricultural and ecological sectors.
The trend of water allocation in the domestic sector across cities remains consistent between the two models. Specifically, in the CIMB-CP model, the domestic water usage proportions for Jingmen, Xiaogan, Xiangyang, and Nanyang are 13%, 12%, 11%, and 7%, respectively, with the combined total for these four cities being 43%. The combined proportion for the remaining cities is 14%, leading to a total domestic water usage of 57%. In the CEMB-CP model, these figures are adjusted upwards, with Jingmen, Xiaogan, Xiangyang, and Nanyang having domestic water usage proportions of 14%, 13%, 12%, and 7%, respectively, amounting to a combined total of 46%. Although the combined proportion for the remaining cities remains at 14%, the overall total increases to 60%. These results indicate that the water distribution trend across major cities remains relatively stable between the two models. Despite slight variations in specific proportions due to differing total water resources, both models exhibit similar prioritization in domestic water allocation across key cities.
4.3. Sensitivity Analysis
In the context of actual negotiations, each participant may adopt different attitudes toward market risk, which can be classified into conservative and aggressive categories. A participant's risk attitude during negotiations influences their perception of risk and reward, expectations of negotiation outcomes, and their willingness to reach an agreement. For instance, conservative participants tend to take cautious actions, preferring stability and conservative results, while aggressive participants are more inclined to assume risks in pursuit of greater benefits and returns.
In the CIMB model, we introduce a discount factor to reflect negotiation cost. Additionally, negotiation cost encompass the maximum bargaining rounds (tmax) and a modulation coefficient (k). As the number of negotiation rounds approaches or reaches tmax, participants experience increased pressure to reach an agreement promptly, avoiding the cost escalation associated with protracted negotiations. The modulation coefficient k is employed to adjust the rate of change in negotiation cost. By manipulating the value of k, we can explore how varying risk attitudes influence the choice of negotiation strategies and decision-making processes. Considering the diverse negotiating environments that participants may face, analyzing the variations in k can reveal the sensitivity of negotiation cost, which is crucial for optimizing negotiation strategies. Consequently, this study establishes five combinations of k values for two players, simulating negotiation scenarios under various risk attitude backgrounds, as detailed in
Table 1.
In various combination scenarios, the solutions of the CIMB model and the final decision outcomes of CIMB-CP are illustrated in
Figure 8. As the value of KB in the combination increases, the final decision reflects a rise in economic benefits alongside an increase in pollution emissions. This indicates that under higher KB values, Player 1's interests are better safeguarded and enhanced, with their financial gains significantly improved. However, this scenario is evidently disadvantageous for Player 2, as the higher pollution emissions lead to increased environmental costs and potential risks. Conversely, when the value of KE in the combination rises, the final decision shows a decrease in pollution emissions and a corresponding drop in economic benefits. This suggests that under higher KE values, Player 2's environmental interests are given more attention and protection, as the reduction in pollution emissions directly lessens their environmental burden. Nevertheless, this scenario adversely affects Player 1, as their economic gains are suppressed.
Furthermore, an analysis of total water usage data across different combination scenarios (S1 to S5) reveals a gradual decline in water allocation, from 16.22 billion cubic meters in S1 to 12.77 billion cubic meters in S5, a decrease of 21.3%. This is because allocating more water resources leads to greater benefits but also results in higher pollution emissions.
The utility results calculated using the max-min approach are shown in
Figure 8(b). Regardless of which player holds a stronger position, they cannot achieve a satisfactory compromise solution. For instance, in scenarios S1 and S5, utility points of (0.9820, 0.1910) and (0.2054, 0.9822) are provided for Player 1 and Player 2, respectively. The distribution of these utility points shows extreme deviation, indicating that such decision solutions are unlikely to emerge in normal decision-making processes and are typically not adopted in negotiations. In scenario S1, Player 1's utility value is near maximization (0.9820), but Player 2's value is extremely low (0.1910), demonstrating Player 1's significant advantage, while Player 2 benefits little from the negotiation. Conversely, in scenario S5, Player 2's utility value is near maximization (0.9822), while Player 1's value is very low (0.2054), presenting an opposite extreme effect to that of scenario S1.
In contrast to these extreme scenarios, when KB and KE values are comparable and both players maintain equal standing, their utility points are more balanced. For example, in scenario S3, the utility point is (0.8610, 0.8415), indicating that the players can achieve fairly equal utility values and thus a fair and balanced decision solution. Such decisions are generally more acceptable to both parties as they avoid one-sided excessive benefits.
During negotiation and decision-making, both players must consider not only their economic gains but also weigh the costs associated with environmental protection. The different combinations of KB and KE directly affect the balance between economic and environmental benefits for both parties. While Player 1 may pursue greater economic benefits, they might overlook the exacerbation of environmental impacts, making a rigid choice between gains and long-term environmental damage. Player 2, on the other hand, focuses more on reducing pollution emissions but faces sacrifices in economic benefits. Understanding and analyzing the impact of KB and KE in various combination scenarios is crucial for effective negotiation and decision-making. To achieve a more balanced and sustainable outcome, it is recommended that both parties engage in thorough communication and consultation when setting KB and KE values, aiming for a more reasonable balance between economic benefits and environmental protection. This would not only contribute to a healthier ecological environment but also ensure the consideration and maximization of both parties' economic interests.